Chapter 6
Extensions of the Two-Variable Linear Regression Model
169
21
A. W.
Phillips, “The Relationship between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages
in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957,”
Economica,
November 1958, vol. 15, pp. 283–299. Note that
the original curve did not cross the unemployment rate axis, but Fig. 6.8 represents
a later version of
the curve.
22
See Olivier Blanchard,
Macroeconomics,
Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1997, Chap. 17.
(
Continued
)
FIGURE 6.8
The Phillips curve.
Rate of change of money wages, %
The natural rate of unemployment
Unemployment rate, %
U
N
–
1
β
0
One of the important applications of Figure 6.6
b
is the
celebrated Phillips curve of
macroeconomics. Using the data on percent rate of change of money wages (
Y
) and the
unemployment rate (
X
) for the United Kingdom for the period 1861–1957, Phillips
obtained a curve whose general shape resembles Figure 6.6
b
(Figure 6.8).
21
As Figure 6.8 shows, there is an asymmetry in the response of wage changes to the level
of the unemployment rate: Wages rise faster for a unit change in unemployment if the
unemployment rate is below
U
N
, which is called the
natural rate of unemployment
by econ-
omists (defined as the rate of unemployment required to keep [wage] inflation constant),
and then they fall slowly for an equivalent change when the unemployment rate is above
the natural rate,
U
N
, indicating the asymptotic floor, or
−
β
1
, for wage change. This partic-
ular feature of the Phillips curve may be due to institutional factors, such as union bargaining
power, minimum wages, unemployment compensation, etc.
Since the publication of Phillips’s article, there has been very
extensive research on the
Phillips curve at the theoretical as well as empirical levels. Space does not permit us to go
into the details of the controversy surrounding the Phillips curve. The Phillips curve itself
has gone through several incarnations. A comparatively recent formulation is provided by
Olivier Blanchard.
22
If we let
π
t
denote
the inflation rate at time
t
, which is defined as the
percentage change in the price level as measured by a representative price index, such as
the Consumer Price Index (CPI), and UN
t
denote the
unemployment rate at time
t
, then a
modern version of the Phillips curve can be expressed in the following format:
π
t
−
π
e
t
=
β
2
(UN
t
−
U
N
)
+
u
t
(6.7.3)
where
π
t
=
actual inflation rate at time
t
π
e
t
=
expected inflation rate at time
t
, the expectation being
formed in year (
t
−
1)
EXAMPLE 6.6
(
Continued
)
guj75772_ch06.qxd 23/08/2008 03:18 PM Page 169