subintervals. As we do, the stock price distribution becomes increasingly plausible, as we
In Example 21.2, we broke up the year into three subperiods. Let’s now look at the cases
C H A P T E R
2 1
Option
Valuation
735
Figure 21.5
Probability distributions for final stock price. Possible outcomes and associated probabilities.
In each panel, the stock’s annualized, continuously compounded expected rate of return is 10% and its
standard deviation is 30%. Panel A. Three subintervals. In each subinterval, the stock can increase by 18.9%
or fall by 15.9%. Panel B. Six subintervals. In each subinterval, the stock can increase by 13.0% or fall by
11.5%. Panel C. Twenty subintervals. In each subinterval, the stock can increase by 6.9% or fall by 6.5%.
.00
.05
.10
.15
.20
.25
.30
.35
.40
25
50
75
100 125 150 175 200 225 250
Final Stock Price
.45
Probability
A
.00
.05
.10
.15
.20
.25
.30
.35
25
50
75
100 125 150 175 200 225 250
Final Stock Price
Probability
B
.00
.05
.10
.15
.20
25
50
75
100 125 150 175 200 225 250
Final Stock Price
C
Probability
We plot the resulting probability distributions in panels B and C of Figure 21.5 .
5
Notice that the right tail of the distribution in panel C is noticeably longer than
the left tail. In fact, as the number of intervals increases, the distribution progressively
approaches the skewed log-normal (rather than the symmetric normal) distribution. Even
if the stock price were to decline in each subinterval, it can never drop below zero. But
there is no corresponding upper bound on its potential performance. This asymmetry
gives rise to the skewness of the distribution.
Eventually, as we divide the option maturity into an ever-greater number of subintervals,
each node of the event tree would correspond to an infinitesimally small time interval. The
possible stock price movement within that time interval would be correspondingly small.
As those many intervals passed, the end-of-period stock price would more and more closely
5
We adjust the probabilities of up versus down movements using the formula in footnote 4 to make the distribu-
tions in Figure 21.5 comparable. In each panel,
p is chosen so that the stock’s expected annualized, continuously
compounded rate of return is 10%.
bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 735
bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 735
7/27/13 1:45 AM
7/27/13 1:45 AM
Final PDF to printer
736
resemble a lognormal distribution.
6
Thus the apparent oversimplification of the two-state
model can be overcome by progressively subdividing any period into many subperiods.
At any node, one still could set up a portfolio that would be perfectly hedged over the
next tiny time interval. Then, at the end of that interval, on reaching the next node, a new
hedge ratio could be computed and the portfolio composition could be revised to remain
6
Actually, more complex considerations enter here. The limit of this process is lognormal only if we assume
also that stock prices move continuously, by which we mean that over small time intervals only small price
movements can occur. This rules out rare events such as sudden, extreme price moves in response to dramatic
information (like a takeover attempt). For a treatment of this type of “jump process,” see John C. Cox and Stephen
A. Ross, “The Valuation of Options for Alternative Stochastic Processes,” Journal of Financial Economics 3
(January–March 1976), pp. 145–66, or Robert C. Merton, “Option Pricing When Underlying Stock Returns Are
Discontinuous,” Journal of Financial Economics 3 (January–March 1976), pp. 125–44.
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: