c h i n a’s p o l i t i c a l c r i s i s
Japan solved its problem with a generation of low growth. It had the politi
cal and social discipline to do this without unrest. East Asia solved it in two
ways. Some countries, like South Korea and Taiwan, imposed painful mea
sures and came out stronger than ever, but this was possible only because
they had strong states able to impose pain. Some countries, like Indonesia,
never really recovered.
The problem for China is political. China is held together by money,
not ideology. When there is an economic downturn and the money stops
rolling in, not only will the banking system spasm, but the entire fabric of
Chinese society will shudder. Loyalty in China is either bought or coerced.
Without available money, only coercion remains. Business slowdowns can
generally lead to instability because they lead to business failure and unem
ployment. In a country where poverty is endemic and unemployment wide
spread, the added pressure of an economic downturn will result in political
instability.
Recall how China split into coastal and interior regions between the
British intrusion and Mao’s triumph. Businesses on the coast, prosperous
from foreign trade and investment, gravitated to their foreign interests, try
ing to break free from the central government. They drew in European
imperialists—and Americans—who had financial interests in China. To
day’s situation is potentially the same. A businessman in Shanghai has inter
ests in common with Los Angeles, New York, and London. In fact, he
makes far more money from these relationships than he does from Beijing.
As Beijing tries to clamp down on him, not only will he want to break free
of its control, but he will try to draw in foreign powers to protect his and
their interests. In the meantime, the much poorer people in the interior of
the country will be either trying to move to the coastal cities or pressuring
Beijing to tax the coast and give them money. Beijing, caught in the middle,
either weakens and loses control or clamps down so hard that it moves back
97
c h i n a 2 0 2 0
to a Maoist enclosure of the country. The critical question is which outcome
is more likely.
The Chinese regime rests on two pillars. One is the vast bureaucracy that
operates China. The second is the military- security complex that enforces
the will of the state and the Communist Party. A third pillar, the ideological
principles of the Communist Party, has now disappeared. Egalitarianism,
selflessness, and service to the people are now archaic values, preached but
not believed by or practiced by the Chinese people.
State, party, and security apparati are as affected by the decline in ideol
ogy as the rest of society. Communist Party officials have been the personal
beneficiaries of the new order. If the regime were to try to bring the coastal
regions under control, it is hard to imagine the apparatus being particularly
aggressive, as it is part of the same system that enriched those regions. In the
nineteenth century the same problem emerged when government officials
along the coast didn’t want to enforce Beijing’s edicts. They were on the side
of doing business with foreigners.
If there is indeed a serious economic crisis, the central government will
have to find a substitute ideology for communism. If people are to sacrifice,
it must be for something they believe in—and if the Chinese cannot believe
in communism, they can still believe in China. The Chinese government
will attempt to limit disintegration by increasing nationalism and the natu
ral companion of nationalism, xenophobia. Historically, China has a deep
distrust of foreigners, and the party will need to blame someone for eco
nomic devastation. As Mao blamed foreigners for China’s weakness and
poverty, the party will again blame foreigners for China’s economic problems.
Since there will be substantial confrontations with foreign states on eco
nomic issues—they will be defending their economic investments in China—
playing the nationalist card will come easily. The idea of China as a great
power will substitute for the lost ideology of communism. Disputes will
help bolster the position of the Chinese government. By blaming foreigners
for problems and confronting foreign governments diplomatically and with
growing military power, the Chinese will generate public support for the
regime. This is most likely to take place in the 2010s.
The most natural confrontation would be with Japan and/or the United
States, both historical enemies with whom smoldering disputes already ex
98
t h e n e x t 1 0 0 y e a r s
ist. Russia is unlikely to be treated as an enemy. However, the probability of
a military confrontation with the Japanese or the Americans is limited. It
would be difficult for the Chinese to engage either country aggressively. The
Chinese have a weak navy that could not survive a confrontation with the
United States. Therefore, invading Taiwan might be tempting in theory but
is not likely to happen. China does not have the naval power to force its way
across the Taiwan Strait, and certainly not the ability to protect convoys
shuttling supplies to Taiwanese battlefields. China is not going to develop a
naval capacity that can challenge the United States within a decade. It takes
a long time to build a navy.
China, then, has three possible future paths. In the first, it continues to grow
at astronomical rates indefinitely. No country has ever done that, and China
is not likely to be an exception. The extraordinary growth of the past thirty
years has created huge imbalances and inefficiencies in China’s economy
that will have to be corrected. At some point China will have to go through
the kind of wrenching readjustment that the rest of Asia already has under
gone.
A second possible path is the recentralization of China, where the con
flicting interests that will emerge and compete following an economic slow
down are controlled by a strong central government that imposes order and
restricts the regions’ room to maneuver. That scenario is more probable than
the first, but the fact that the apparatus of the central government is filled
with people whose own interests oppose centralization would make this dif
ficult to pull off. The government can’t necessarily rely on its own people to
enforce the rules. Nationalism is the only tool they have to hold things
together.
A third possibility is that under the stress of an economic downturn,
China fragments along traditional regional lines, while the central govern
ment weakens and becomes less powerful. Traditionally, this is a more plau
sible scenario in China—and one that will benefit the wealthier classes as
well as foreign investors. It will leave China in the position it was in prior to
Mao, with regional competition and perhaps even conflict and a central gov
ernment struggling to maintain control. If we accept the fact that China’s
99
c h i n a 2 0 2 0
economy will have to undergo a readjustment at some point, and that this
will generate serious tension, as it would in any country, then this third out
come fits most closely with reality and with Chinese history.
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |