Performance Provided,
Market Demand, and the
Product Life Cycle
The graphs in this book showing the intersecting technology and market trajectories have proven useful
in explaining how leading firms can stumble from positions of industry leadership. In each of the
several industries explored, technologists were able to provide rates of performance improvement that
have exceeded the rates of performance improvement that the market has needed or was able to absorb.
Historically, when this performance oversupply occurs, it creates an opportunity for a disruptive
technology to emerge and subsequently to invade established markets from below.
As it creates this threat or opportunity for a disruptive technology, performance oversupply also
triggers a fundamental change in the basis of competition in the product’s market: The rank-ordering of
the criteria by which customers choose one product or service over another will change, signaling a
transition from one phase (variously defined by management theorists) to the next of the product life
cycle. In other words, the intersecting trajectories of performance supplied and performance demanded
are fundamental triggers behind the phases in the product life cycle. Because of this, trajectory maps
such as those used in this book usefully characterize how an industry’s competitive dynamics and its
basis of competition are likely to change over time.
As with past chapters, this discussion begins with an analysis from the disk drive industry of what can
happen when the performance supplied exceeds the market’s demands. After seeing the same
phenomenon played out in the markets for accounting software and for diabetes care products, the link
between this pattern and the phases of the product life cycle will be clear.
PERFORMANCE OVERSUPPLY AND CHANGING BASES OF COMPETITION
The phenomenon of performance oversupply is charted in Figure 9.1, an extract from Figure 1.7. It
shows that by 1988, the capacity of the average 3.5-inch drive had finally increased to equal the
capacity demanded in the mainstream desktop personal computer market, and that the capacity of the
average 5.25-inch drive had by that time surpassed what the mainstream desktop market demanded by
nearly 300 percent. At this point, for the first time since the desktop market emerged, computer makers
had a choice of drives to buy: The 5.25- and 3.5-inch drives both provided perfectly adequate capacity.
What was the result? The desktop personal computer makers began switching to 3.5-inch drives in
droves. Figure 9.2 illustrates this, using a substitution curve format in which the vertical axis measures
the ratio of new- to old-technology units sold. In 1985 this measure was .007, meaning that less than 1
percent (.0069) of the desktop market had switched to the 3.5-inch format. By 1987, the ratio had
advanced 0.20, meaning that 16.7 percent of the units sold into this market that year were 3.5-inch
145
drives. By 1989, the measure was 1.5, that is, only four years after the 3.5-inch product had appeared as
a faint blip on the radar screen of the market, it accounted for 60 percent of drive sales.
Why did the 3.5-inch drive so decisively conquer the desktop PC market? A standard economic guess
might be that the 3.5-inch format represented a more cost-effective architecture: If there were no longer
any meaningful differentiation between two types of products (both had adequate capacity), price
competition would intensify. This was not the case here, however. Indeed, computer makers had to pay,
on average, 20 percent more per megabyte to use 3.5-inch drives, and yet they still flocked to the
product. Moreover, computer manufacturers opted for the costlier drive while facing fierce price
competition in their own product markets. Why?
Figure 9.1 Intersecting Trajectories of Capacity Demanded versus Capacity Supplied in Rigid Disk
Drives
Source: Data are from various issues of Disk/Trend Report.
Performance oversupply triggered a change in the basis of competition. Once the demand for capacity
was satiated, other attributes, whose performance had not yet satisfied market demands, came to be
more highly valued and to constitute the dimensions along which drive makers sought to differentiate
their products. In concept, this meant that the most important attribute measured on the vertical axis of
figures such as 8.1 changed, and that new trajectories of product performance, compared to market
demands, took shape.
146
Specifically, in the desktop personal computer marketplace between 1986 and 1988, the smallness of
the drive began to matter more than other features. The smaller 3.5-inch drive allowed computer
manufacturers to reduce the size, or desktop footprint, of their machines. At IBM, for example, the
large XT/AT box gave way to the much smaller PS1/PS2 generation machines.
Figure 9.2 Substitution of 8-, 5.25-, and 3.5-Inch Drives of 30 to 100 MB
Source: Data are from various issues of Disk/Trend Report.
For a time, when the availability of small drives did not satisfy market demands, desktop computer
makers continued to pay a hefty premium for 3.5-inch drives. In fact, using the hedonic regression
analysis described in chapter 4, the 1986 shadow price for a one-cubic-inch reduction in the volume of
a disk drive was $4.72. But once the computer makers had configured their new generations of desktop
machines to use the smaller drive, their demand for even more smallness was satiated. As a result, the
1989 shadow price, or the price premium accorded to smaller drives, diminished to $0.06 for a one-
cubic-inch reduction.
Generally, once the performance level demanded of a particular attribute has been achieved, customers
indicate their satiation by being less willing to pay a premium price for continued improvement in that
attribute. Hence, performance oversupply triggers a shift in the basis of competition, and the criteria
used by customers to choose one product over another changes to attributes for which market demands
are not yet satisfied.
Figure 9.3 summarizes what seems to have happened in the desktop PC market: The attribute measured
on the vertical axis repeatedly changed. Performance oversupply in capacity triggered the first
redefinition of the vertical axis, from capacity to physical size. When performance on this new
147
dimension satisfied market needs, the definition of performance on the vertical axis changed once
more, to reflect demand for reliability. For a time, products offering competitively superior shock
resistance and mean time between failure (MTBF) were accorded a significant price premium,
compared to competitive offerings. But as MTBF values approached one million hours,
1
the shadow
price accorded to an increment of one hundred hours MTBF approached zero, suggesting performance
oversupply on that dimension of product performance. The subsequent and current phase is an intense
price-based competition, with gross margins tumbling below 12 percent in some instances.
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |