How bad could it get? America’s ugly election



Download 13,31 Mb.
Pdf ko'rish
bet80/104
Sana01.01.2022
Hajmi13,31 Mb.
#305598
1   ...   76   77   78   79   80   81   82   83   ...   104
Bog'liq
The Economist - UK 2020-09-05

Culture club

The revival of cultural explanations for

wealth and poverty seems to be a method-

ological step forward. Yet it raises two big

questions. The first concerns the origins of

cultural traits: where do they come from?

The second is why people from apparently

similar cultures sometimes have very dif-

ferent economic outcomes. To answer

these questions, economists have come to

appreciate the importance of history—and,

in particular, historical accident. 

Take first the question of the origin of

cultural traits. Some research suggests that

they are the product of changes which took

place hundreds of years ago. A 2013 paper

by the late Alberto Alesina and two of his

colleagues looks at why countries have

very different rates of female labour-force

participation. Egypt and Namibia are about

as rich as each other, but the share of Na-

mibian women in the labour force is more

than twice that of Egyptian women. The pa-

per puts such differences largely down to

differences in pre-industrial agriculture

and environmental conditions. Plough

cultivation, common in Egypt, required

lots of upper-body strength—so men were

at an advantage. Shifting cultivation, more

common in Namibia, used hand-held tools

like the hoe which suited women better.

The effect of these agricultural technol-

ogies echoes in statistics today. 

Other economists look to the distant

past to explain contemporary disparities in

income and wealth. A paper from last year

by Benjamin Enke of Harvard University

finds evidence that pre-industrial ethnici-

ties which were exposed to a high local

prevalence of pathogens exhibited tighter

kinship systems—meaning, in effect, that

people were strongly loyal to their extend-

ed family but suspicious of outsiders. In a

place threatened by disease, tight family

ties were beneficial because they reduced

the need to travel, and therefore the risk of

being exposed. Places which had tighter

kinship systems hundreds of years ago

tend to be poorer today, a relationship

which first emerged during the industrial

revolution. Other research has looked even

further back, suggesting that contempo-

rary cultural traits are the result of genetic

variation. But this remains a niche pursuit,

and most economists turn queasy when it

comes to talking about genetics. 

A separate body of research focuses on

cases where culture is not a sufficient ex-

planation for economic outcomes. Take

the case of Guatemala and Costa Rica. “The

two countries had similar histories, simi-

lar geographies and cultural inheritance,

and were faced with the same economic

opportunities in the 19th century,” write

Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson in

“The Narrow Corridor”, a book published

last year. But today the average Costa Rican

is more than twice as rich as the average

Guatemalan. The cause of the divergence

initially appeared random, according to Mr

Acemoglu and Mr Robinson. Eventually it

became clear it was down to coffee. In Costa

Rica the development of coffee plantations

for the European market led to a more bal-

anced relationship between state and soci-

ety, possibly because the country had more

marginal land and more smallholders. In

Guatemala, by contrast, it led to the emer-

gence of a rapacious government.

In addition to culture, therefore, a grow-

ing band of economists is looking at “insti-

tutions”, often taken to mean the legal sys-

tem and regulations. Some cultural

economists argue that the focus on institu-

tions proves their point: what are institu-

tions if not the product of norms, values

and preferences? Americans’ and Euro-

peans’ differing beliefs about the causes of

inequality, for instance, go a long way to-

wards explaining why European welfare

states are more generous than America’s. 

But in many cases the emergence of dif-

ferent institutions may have nothing to do

with a country’s culture. Sometimes it is

just luck. Mr Mokyr shows that Europe,

which was fragmented into lots of states,

was the perfect setting for innovation: in-

tellectuals who challenged received wis-

dom and incurred the wrath of the authori-

ties could move elsewhere (Thomas

Hobbes wrote “Leviathan” in Paris). By con-

trast in China, Mr Mokyr argues, free think-

ers had few escape routes. Europeans did

not plan such a system. It just happened. 

Other work by Mr Acemoglu and Mr

Robinson, along with Simon Johnson of

mit

, has found a further element of ran-



domness which may explain contempo-

rary patterns of wealth and poverty—

namely, which countries are more prone to

certain diseases. The mortality rate of set-

tlers was low in some colonised countries,

such as New Zealand and Australia, in part

because the kinds of diseases that were

there were less virulent. In others, such as

Mali and Nigeria, mortality rates were far

higher. Colonisers did not want to settle in

countries with a high risk of disease, even

as they wanted to take those countries’ raw

materials. So in countries such as Mali and

Nigeria, rather than permanently settling,

they set up systems which enabled the

maximum of resource extraction with the

fewest boots on the ground. That, say

Messrs Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson,

produced rapacious political systems

which have endured to this day. 

Are economists any closer to answering

the foundational question of their science?

Far from the simplistic certainty of Weber,

it seems likely that some countries are rich

and others poor because of a messy combi-

nation of economic incentives, culture, in-

stitutions and chance—which is most im-

portant remains unclear. In 1817  Thomas

Malthus, one of the early economists,

wrote in a letter to David Ricardo, another,

that “the causes of the wealth and poverty

of nations [were] the grand object of all en-

quiries in Political Economy”. The revival

of cultural economics two centuries on has

helped in that quest, but it is not over yet. 

7


Download 13,31 Mb.

Do'stlaringiz bilan baham:
1   ...   76   77   78   79   80   81   82   83   ...   104




Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©hozir.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling

kiriting | ro'yxatdan o'tish
    Bosh sahifa
юртда тантана
Боғда битган
Бугун юртда
Эшитганлар жилманглар
Эшитмадим деманглар
битган бодомлар
Yangiariq tumani
qitish marakazi
Raqamli texnologiyalar
ilishida muhokamadan
tasdiqqa tavsiya
tavsiya etilgan
iqtisodiyot kafedrasi
steiermarkischen landesregierung
asarlaringizni yuboring
o'zingizning asarlaringizni
Iltimos faqat
faqat o'zingizning
steierm rkischen
landesregierung fachabteilung
rkischen landesregierung
hamshira loyihasi
loyihasi mavsum
faolyatining oqibatlari
asosiy adabiyotlar
fakulteti ahborot
ahborot havfsizligi
havfsizligi kafedrasi
fanidan bo’yicha
fakulteti iqtisodiyot
boshqaruv fakulteti
chiqarishda boshqaruv
ishlab chiqarishda
iqtisodiyot fakultet
multiservis tarmoqlari
fanidan asosiy
Uzbek fanidan
mavzulari potok
asosidagi multiservis
'aliyyil a'ziym
billahil 'aliyyil
illaa billahil
quvvata illaa
falah' deganida
Kompyuter savodxonligi
bo’yicha mustaqil
'alal falah'
Hayya 'alal
'alas soloh
Hayya 'alas
mavsum boyicha


yuklab olish