Bank Runs and Banking Crises
Financial institutions are inherently fragile entities, giving rise to many possible coordination
problems. Because of their roles in maturity transformation and liquidity creation, financial
institutions operate with highly leveraged balance sheets. Hence, banking, and other similar
forms of financial intermediation, can be precarious undertakings. Fragility makes
coordination, or lack thereof, a major challenge in financial markets. Coordination problems
arise when investors and/or institutions take actions – like withdrawing liquidity or capital –
merely out of fear that others also take similar actions. Given this fragility, a crisis can easily
take place, where large amounts of liquidity or capital are withdrawn because of a self-
fulfilling belief – it happens because investors fear it will happen. Small shocks, whether real
or financial, can translate into turmoil in markets and even a financial crisis.
A simple example of a coordination problem is a bank run. It is a truism that banks borrow
short and lend long. This maturity transformation reflects preferences of consumers and
borrowers. However, it makes banks vulnerable to sudden demands for liquidity, i.e., “runs”
(the seminal reference here is Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). A run occurs when a large
number of customers withdraw their deposits because they believe the bank is, or might
become, insolvent. As a bank run proceeds, it generates its own momentum, leading to a self-
fulfilling prophecy (or perverse feedback loop): as more people withdraw their deposits, the
likelihood of default increases, and this encourages further withdrawals. This can destabilize
the bank to the point where it faces bankruptcy as it cannot liquidate assets fast enough to
cover its short-term liabilities.
These fragilities have long been recognized, and markets, institutions, and policy makers
have developed many “coping” mechanisms (see further Dewatripoint and Tirole, 1994).
Market discipline encourages institutions to limit vulnerabilities. At the firm level,
intermediaries have adopted risk management strategies to reduce their fragility.
19
Furthermore, micro-prudential regulation, with supervision to enforce rules, is designed to
reduce risky behavior of individual financial institutions and can help engineer stability.
Deposit insurance can eliminate concerns of small depositors and can help reduce
coordination problems. Lender of last resort facilities (i.e., central banks) can provide short-
run liquidity to banks during periods of elevated financial stress. Policy interventions by
public sector, such as public guarantees, capital support and purchases of non-performing
assets, can mitigate systemic risk when financial turmoil hits.
Although regulation and safety net measures can help, when poorly designed or implemented
they can increase the likelihood of a banking crisis. Regulations aim to reduce fragilities (for
example, limits on balance sheet mismatches stemming from interest rate, exchange rate,
maturity mismatches, or certain activities of financial institutions). Regulation (and
supervision), however, often finds itself playing catch up with innovation. And it can be
poorly designed or implemented. Support from the public sector can also have distortionary
effects (see further Barth, Caprio and Levine, 2006). Moral hazard due to a state guarantee
(e.g., explicit or implicit deposit insurance) may, for example, lead banks to assume too
much leverage. Institutions that know they are too big to fail or unwind, can take excessive
risks, thereby creating systemic vulnerabilities.
15
More generally, fragilities in the banking
system can arise because of policies at both micro and macro levels (Laeven, 2011).
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |