been difficult, and it becomes even more difficult if there are financial
innovations and money demand shocks. Thus for some years, the focus of
monetary policy analysis has been the appropriate contingent rule for short-
term nominal interest rates. The Taylor rule has provided the appropriate
framework, because it allows for reactions of the central bank policy rate to
the
natural rate of interest, deviations of inflation from the low-inflation
target, and deviations of output or employment from their natural rates. It
provides flexibility and allows the central bank to pursue a low-inflation
objective over the business cycle, which also results in low nominal interest
rates.
A final conclusion is that with a low-inflation objective, there is always
the risk that a big enough negative shock to aggregate demand will force
monetary policy to hit the zero lower bound of interest rates. In such cases,
and especially in the presence of financial frictions, the short-run nominal
interest rate ceases to be an effective instrument of monetary policy. Then
central banks must follow unconventional monetary policies, such as forward
guidance,
quantitative easing, and asset purchases.
1
. For example, in chapter 6, we investigated the effects of fiscal policy variables, such as government
expenditure, taxes, and government debt, on economic growth. In chapter 7, we investigated the effects
of the money supply and monetary growth on economic growth and nominal variables, such as the price
level, inflation, and nominal interest rates. In chapter 12, we investigated the implications of monetary
growth and central bank interest rate policy on prices and inflation. In chapters 14–17, we investigated
the effects of alternative rules for the money supply and nominal interest rates for aggregate
fluctuations in real and nominal variables. In chapter 18, we investigated the effects of unemployment
benefit systems on equilibrium unemployment. In most cases, the policy variables (or the parameters of
the policy rules determining them) were treated as exogenous.
2
. See chapter 15 for a discussion of the rules versus discretion debate in the context of the Phillips
curve. Fischer [1990] surveys the literature on rules versus discretion for monetary policy.
3
. Chapters 12 and 15 introduced this discussion. The classic analysis of the appropriate choice of
monetary instruments in a Keynesian model was Poole [1970], who conducted his analysis on the basis
of the Tinbergen [1952]–Theil [1954] framework, which stressed the distinction between policy
instruments and policy targets. Sargent and Wallace [1975] demonstrated that under rational
expectations, a noncontingent interest rate target leads to price level indeterminacy and instability (see
chapter 12). However, it is now accepted that this problem does not arise in the case of contingent
interest rate rules that allow for the nominal interest rate to depend on the price level (McCallum
[1981]), or to be a sufficiently sensitive positive function of inflation. See Woodford [2003a], chapter 1
and chapter 12, for the relevant arguments. In any case, central banks have been consistently using
interest rates as their main monetary policy instrument. As noted by Bernanke [2006, p. 2], “In practice,
the
difficulty has been that, deregulation, financial innovation, and other factors have led to recurrent
instability in the relationships between various monetary aggregates and other nominal variables.”
4
. See Clarida et al. [1999], Woodford [2003a, 2011] Gali [2008, 2011a,b], and Taylor and Williams
[2011] for surveys of the findings of this literature. Woodford [2003a] and Orphanides [2003c, 2008]
survey the analysis of interest rate rules from Wicksell [1898] to Taylor [1993].
5
. One could of course use the staggered pricing model of chapter 16 to analyze optimal monetary
policy. For analyses of monetary policy based on this
type of new Keynesian model, see Woodford
[2003a] and Gali [2011b]. Central banks increasingly use empirically estimated generalized new
Keynesian models with both price and wage rigidities to evaluate policy. Such models have been
calibrated, estimated, and empirically implemented by Erceg et al. [2000], Smets and Wouters [2003,
2007], Christiano et al. [2005], and others. However, not all of these models are analytically tractable.
Simpler models, such as the ones we utilize, are better for highlighting
the theoretical basis of the
mechanisms at work.
6
. Equation
(20.2)
is the expectations-augmented Phillips curve derived in chapter 17, with the additional
restriction of lack of persistence (i.e., by imposing
δ
= 0).
7
. As demonstrated in chapter 15, the same outcome would be a feature of an ad hoc model of an
expectations-augmented Phillips curve under adaptive expectations. The only difference is that the
process of convergence to the equilibrium with high inflation will take more time when expectations are
formed adaptively. For a collection of early papers on the issue of credibility of monetary and fiscal
policy, see Persson and Tabellini [1994a].
8
. As noted by Friedman [1968, p. 13]: “Our economic system will work best when producers and
consumers, employers and employees, can proceed with full confidence that the average level of prices
will behave in a known way in the future—preferably that it will be highly stable.”
9
. For example, the Mortensen-Pissarides model that we examined in chapter 18 can be used to suggest
some such policies. See Pissarides [2000].
10
. The analysis of the significance of reputational mechanisms in repeated games is due to Kreps and
Wilson [1982a, b].
11
. See chapter 12, or Woodford [2003a, chapter 1] for the relevant arguments.
12
. See Capie et al. [1994]. As noted by Bernanke [2006, p. 2], “In practice, the difficulty has been that,
deregulation, financial innovation, and other factors have led to recurrent instability in the relationships
between various monetary aggregates and other nominal variables.”
13
. Obviously, these rules can always be expressed as contingent rules
for the money supply by
substituting for the nominal interest rate in a money demand function and solving for the money supply.
14
. Taylor [1993, 1999] proposed a rule in which the natural real rate of interest was constant at 2% and
the inflation target was equal to 2% as well. Let us term this rule the
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: