natural resources. Moreover, the nature of capitalist
economies as they have
developed over the same time period has been such that it was inevitable
that in the advanced industrial countries ‘ownership’ would not be inter-
preted as ‘stewardship’ but as ‘dominion’. Natural resources were there to be
exploited for gain by landowners, the state, and perhaps, at least in modern
welfare capitalist societies, the people. However, even in the latter case, ‘the
people’ means ‘citizens of the state in question’ and not people generally:
until
comparatively recently, the idea that a state might be held globally
accountable for economic activities conducted on its territory would have
seemed incompatible with the first principles of the system.
This attitude began to change in the late 1960s and early 1970s. In the
first place it became clear that certain kinds of economic activity could
have quite dramatic effects beyond the borders of the state in question: the
phenomenon of ‘acid rain’ is paradigmatic here, with deforestation in, for
example, Scandinavia or Canada caused by industrial pollution originating
in Britain, Germany or the United States. However, although these are serious
issues, they pose no particularly interesting theoretical problems. In principle,
cross-border pollution is much the
same as intra-border pollution; cleaning
up the Rhine (which flows through several states) is more complicated than
cleaning up the Thames, but poses the same sort of problems – in particular,
how to cost what economists call ‘externalities’, whether to regard pollu-
tion control as a general charge on taxation or something that can be han-
dled on the basis that the polluter pays, and so on. Once the problem is
recognized, capitalist economies have fewer problems dealing with this sort
of question than one might expect. Private ownership cuts both ways – it
can
hinder collective action, but it also means that it is, in principle, possible
to identify and hold accountable the agents of environmental degradation.
An interesting contrast here is with the far greater difficulties in controlling
direct pollution experienced by communist industrial powers, where ‘public
ownership’ provided a reason for not tackling similar problems, as the post-
communist states which have inherited dead rivers and urban industrial
nightmares have reason to be aware.
Of greater long-term significance was the second reason for the increased
salience of environmental issues in the early 1970s,
namely a growing
consciousness that there might be ‘limits to growth’ (Meadows
et al. 1974).
It was argued that industrial civilization depended on the ever-faster
consumption of materials the supply of which was, by definition, finite.
Hydrocarbon-based fuels that had been created over millions of years were
being consumed in decades. Demand for resources that were, in principle,
renewable – such as wood or agricultural products – was growing faster
than matching supplies, creating other potential shortages a little way down
the line. The point about these rather doom-laden
predictions was that,
unlike phenomena such as acid rain, they challenged the prospects of
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: