1 3 0
PA R T T W O
S U P P LY A N D D E M A N D I : H O W M A R K E T S W O R K
We can, in this case, be precise about how much the curve shifts. Because of
the $0.50 tax levied on buyers, the effective price to buyers is now $0.50 higher
than the market price. For example, if the market price of a cone happened to be
$2.00, the effective price to buyers would be $2.50. Because buyers look at their to-
tal cost including the tax, they demand a quantity of ice cream as if the market
price were $0.50 higher than it actually is. In other words, to induce buyers to de-
mand any given quantity, the market price must now be $0.50 lower to make up
for the effect of the tax. Thus, the tax shifts the demand curve
downward
from
D
1
to
D
2
by exactly the size of the tax ($0.50).
To see
the effect of the tax, we compare the old equilibrium and the new equi-
librium. You can see in the figure that the equilibrium price of ice cream falls from
$3.00 to $2.80 and the equilibrium quantity falls from 100 to 90 cones. Because sell-
ers sell less and buyers buy less in the new equilibrium, the tax on ice cream re-
duces the size of the ice-cream market.
Now let’s return to the question of tax incidence: Who pays the tax? Although
buyers send the entire tax to the government, buyers and sellers share the burden.
Because the market price falls from $3.00 to $2.80 when the tax is introduced, sellers
receive $0.20 less for each ice-cream cone than they did without the tax. Thus, the
tax makes sellers worse off. Buyers pay sellers a lower price ($2.80), but the effective
price including the tax rises from $3.00 before the tax to $3.30 with the tax ($2.80 +
$0.50 = $3.30). Thus, the tax also makes buyers worse off.
To sum up, the analysis yields two general lessons:
◆
Taxes discourage market activity. When a good is taxed, the quantity of the
good sold is smaller in the new equilibrium.
◆
Buyers and sellers share the burden of taxes.
In the new equilibrium, buyers
pay more for the good, and sellers receive less.
H O W TA X E S O N S E L L E R S A F F E C T M A R K E T O U T C O M E S
Now consider a tax levied on sellers of a good.
Suppose the local government
passes a law requiring sellers of ice-cream cones to send $0.50 to the government
for each cone they sell. What are the effects of this law?
In this case, the initial impact of the tax is on the supply of ice cream. Because
the tax is not levied on buyers, the quantity of ice cream demanded at any given
price is the same, so the demand curve does not change. By contrast, the tax on sell-
ers raises the cost of selling ice cream, and leads sellers to supply a smaller quantity
at every price. The supply curve shifts to the left (or, equivalently, upward).
Once again, we can be precise about the magnitude of the shift. For any mar-
ket price of ice cream, the effective price to sellers—the amount they get to keep af-
ter paying the tax—is $0.50 lower. For example, if the market price of a cone
happened to be $2.00, the effective price received by sellers would be $1.50. What-
ever the market price, sellers will supply a quantity of ice cream as if the price
were $0.50 lower than it is. Put differently, to induce sellers to supply any given
quantity, the market price must now be $0.50 higher to compensate for the effect of
the tax. Thus, as shown in Figure 6-7, the supply curve shifts
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: