I n t h I s c h a p t e r y o u w I l L


particular, GDP and the many related statistics



Download 5,6 Mb.
Pdf ko'rish
bet314/472
Sana09.04.2022
Hajmi5,6 Mb.
#539976
1   ...   310   311   312   313   314   315   316   317   ...   472
Bog'liq
[N. Gregory(N. Gregory Mankiw) Mankiw] Principles (BookFi)


particular, GDP and the many related statistics.
The rules of national income accounting include several important identities.
Recall that an 
identity
is an equation that must be true because of the way the vari-
ables in the equation are defined. Identities are useful to keep in mind, for they
clarify how different variables are related to one another. Here we consider some
accounting identities that shed light on the macroeconomic role of financial
markets.
S O M E I M P O R TA N T I D E N T I T I E S
Recall that gross domestic product (GDP) is both total income in an economy
and the total expenditure on the economy’s output of goods and services. GDP
T
HE
U.S. 
STOCK MARKET EXPERIENCED A
quadrupling of stock prices during the
1990s. The following article tries to ex-
plain this remarkable boom. It suggests
that people bid up stock prices because
they came to view stocks as less risky
than they previously thought.
A r e S t o c k s O v e r v a l u e d ?
N o t a C h a n c e
B
Y
J
AMES
K. G
LASSMAN
AND
K
EVIN
A. H
ASSETT
The Dow Jones Industrial Average has
returned more than 200 percent over
the past five years, and the past three
have set an all-time record. So it’s
hardly surprising that many observers
worry the stock market is overvalued.
One of the most popular measures of
valuation, the ratio of a stock’s price to
its earnings per share, P/E, is close to
an all-time high. The P/E of the average
stock on the Dow is 22.5, meaning that
it costs $22.50 to buy $1 in profits—or,
conversely, that an investor’s return
(earnings divided by price) is just 4.4
percent, vs. 5.9 percent for long-term
Treasury bonds.
Yet Warren Buffett, chairman of
Berkshire Hathaway Corp. and the
most successful large-scale investor of
our time, told shareholders in a March
14 letter that “there is no reason to
think of stocks as generally overval-
ued” as long as interest rates remain
low and businesses continue to oper-
ate as profitably as they have in recent
years. Investors were buoyed by this
statement, even though Mr. Buffett
provided no analysis to back up his as-
sertion.
Mr. Buffett is right—and we have
the numbers and the theory to back him
up. Worries about overvaluation, we be-
lieve, are based on a serious and wide-
spread misunderstanding of the returns
and risks associated with equities. We
are not so foolish as to predict the short-
term course of stocks, but we are not re-
luctant to state that, based on modest
assumptions about interest rates and
profit levels, current P/E levels give us
no great concern—nor would levels as
much as twice as high.
The fact is that if you hold stocks in-
stead of bonds the amount of money
flowing into your pockets will be higher
over time. Why? Both bonds and stocks
provide their owners with a flow of cash
over time. For bonds, the arithmetic is
simple: If you buy a $10,000 bond paying
6 percent interest today, you’ll receive
$600 every year. For equities, the math
is more complicated: Assume that a
stock currently yields 2 percent, or $2
for each share priced at $100. Say you
own 100 shares; total dividend payments
are $200—much lower than for bonds.
I N T H E N E W S
The Stock Market Boom
of the 1990s


C H A P T E R 2 5
S AV I N G , I N V E S T M E N T, A N D T H E F I N A N C I A L S Y S T E M
5 6 1
(denoted as 
Y
) is divided into four components of expenditure: consumption (
C
),
investment (
I
), government purchases (
G
), and net exports (
NX
). We write
Y
C
I
G
NX.
This equation is an identity because every dollar of expenditure that shows up on
the left-hand side also shows up in one of the four components on the right-hand
side. Because of the way each of the variables is defined and measured, this equa-
tion must always hold.
In this chapter, we simplify our analysis by assuming that the economy we are
examining is closed. A
closed economy
is one that does not interact with other
economies. In particular, a closed economy does not engage in international trade
in goods and services, nor does it engage in international borrowing and lending.
Of course, actual economies are 
open economies
—that is, they interact with other
economies around the world. (We will examine the macroeconomics of open
economies later in this book.) Nonetheless, assuming a closed economy is a useful
simplification by which we can learn some lessons that apply to all economies.
Moreover, this assumption applies perfectly to the world economy (inasmuch as
interplanetary trade is not yet common).
But wait. There is a big difference.
Profits grow over time. If that dividend
should increase with profits, say at a
rate of 5 percent annually, then, by the
30th year, your annual dividend payment
will be over $800, or one-third more than
the bond is yielding. The price of the
stock almost certainly will have risen
as well.
By this simple exercise, we can see
that stocks—even with their profits
growing at a moderate 5 percent—will
return far more than bonds over long pe-
riods. Over the past 70 years, stocks
have annually returned 4.8 percent-
age points more than long-term U.S.
Treasury bonds and 6.8 points more
than Treasury bills, according to Ibbot-
son Associates Inc., a Chicago research
firm.
But isn’t that extra reward—what
economists call the “equity premium”—
merely the bonus paid by the market to
investors who accept higher risk, since
returns for stocks are so much more un-
certain than for bonds? To this question,
we respond: What extra risk?
In his book “Stocks for the Long
Run,” Jeremy J. Siegel of the University
of Pennsylvania concludes: “It is widely
known that stock returns, on average,
exceed bonds in the long run. But it is lit-
tle known that in the long run, the risks in
stocks are less than those found in
bonds or even bills!” Mr. Siegel looked
at every 20-year holding period from
1802 to 1992 and found that the worst
real return for stocks was an annual av-
erage of 1.2 percent and the best was
an annual average of 12.6 percent. For
long-term bonds, the range was 
minus
3.1 percent to plus 8.8 percent; for T-
bills, minus 3.0 percent to plus 8.3 per-
cent.
Based on these findings, it would
seem that there should be no need for
an equity risk premium at all—and that
the correct valuation for the stock mar-
ket would be one that equalizes the
present value of cash flow between
stocks and bonds in the long run. Think
of the market as offering you two assets,
one that will pay you $1,000 over the
next 30 years in a steady stream and
another that, just as surely, will pay you
the $1,000, but the cash flow will vary
from year to year. Assuming you’re in-
vesting for the long term, you will value
them about the same. . . .
Allow us now to suggest a hypothe-
sis about the huge returns posted by the
stock market over the past few years:
As mutual funds have advertised the re-
duction of risk acquired by taking the
long view, the risk premium required by
shareholders has gradually drifted down.
Since Siegel’s results suggest that the
correct risk premium might be zero, this
drift downward—and the corresponding
trend toward higher stock prices—may
not be over. . . . In the current environ-
ment, we are very comfortable both in
holding stocks and in saying that pundits
who claim the market is overvalued are
foolish.
Source: 
The Wall Street Journal,
Monday, March 30,
1998, p. A18.


5 6 2
PA R T N I N E
T H E R E A L E C O N O M Y I N T H E L O N G R U N
Because a closed economy does not engage in international trade, imports and
exports are exactly zero. Therefore, net exports (
NX
) are also zero. In this case, we
can write
Y
C
I
G.
This equation states that GDP is the sum of consumption, investment, and gov-
ernment purchases. Each unit of output sold in a closed economy is consumed, in-
vested, or bought by the government.
To see what this identity can tell us about financial markets, subtract 
C
and 
G
from both sides of this equation. We obtain
Y
C
G
I.
The left-hand side of this equation (
Y
C
G
) is the total income in the economy
that remains after paying for consumption and government purchases: This
amount is called 

Download 5,6 Mb.

Do'stlaringiz bilan baham:
1   ...   310   311   312   313   314   315   316   317   ...   472




Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©hozir.org 2025
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling

kiriting | ro'yxatdan o'tish
    Bosh sahifa
юртда тантана
Боғда битган
Бугун юртда
Эшитганлар жилманглар
Эшитмадим деманглар
битган бодомлар
Yangiariq tumani
qitish marakazi
Raqamli texnologiyalar
ilishida muhokamadan
tasdiqqa tavsiya
tavsiya etilgan
iqtisodiyot kafedrasi
steiermarkischen landesregierung
asarlaringizni yuboring
o'zingizning asarlaringizni
Iltimos faqat
faqat o'zingizning
steierm rkischen
landesregierung fachabteilung
rkischen landesregierung
hamshira loyihasi
loyihasi mavsum
faolyatining oqibatlari
asosiy adabiyotlar
fakulteti ahborot
ahborot havfsizligi
havfsizligi kafedrasi
fanidan bo’yicha
fakulteti iqtisodiyot
boshqaruv fakulteti
chiqarishda boshqaruv
ishlab chiqarishda
iqtisodiyot fakultet
multiservis tarmoqlari
fanidan asosiy
Uzbek fanidan
mavzulari potok
asosidagi multiservis
'aliyyil a'ziym
billahil 'aliyyil
illaa billahil
quvvata illaa
falah' deganida
Kompyuter savodxonligi
bo’yicha mustaqil
'alal falah'
Hayya 'alal
'alas soloh
Hayya 'alas
mavsum boyicha


yuklab olish