one’s investment to increase the potential rewards as well as
the risks. Such devices helped to ensure broad participation in
the market. The same is true today.
The history of the period
was filled with tragicomic
episodes. One such incident concerned a returning sailor who
brought news to a wealthy merchant of the arrival of a
shipment of new goods. The merchant rewarded him with a
breakfast of fine red herring. Seeing what he thought was an
onion on the merchant’s counter, and no doubt thinking it
very much out of place amid silks and velvets, he proceeded
to take it as a relish for his herring. Little did he dream that
the “onion” would have fed a whole ship’s crew for a year. It
was a costly Semper Augustus tulip bulb. The sailor paid
dearly for his relish—his no
longer grateful host had him
imprisoned for several months on a felony charge.
Historians regularly reinterpret the past, and some
financial historians who have reexamined the evidence about
various financial bubbles have argued that considerable
rationality in pricing may have existed after all. One of these
revisionist historians, Peter Garber, has suggested that tulip-
bulb pricing in seventeenth-century
Holland was far more
rational than is commonly believed.
Garber makes some good points, and I do not mean to
imply that there was no rationality at all in the structure of
bulb prices during the period. The Semper Augustus, for
example, was a particularly
rare and beautiful bulb and, as
Garber reveals, was valued greatly even in the years before
the tulipmania. Moreover, Garber’s research indicates that
rare individual bulbs commanded
high prices even after the
general collapse of bulb prices, albeit at levels that were only
a fraction of their peak prices. But Garber can find no rational
explanation for such phenomena as a twenty-fold increase in
tulip-bulb prices during January of 1637 followed by an even
larger decline in prices in February. Apparently, as happens
in all speculative crazes, prices eventually got so high that
some people decided they would be prudent and sell their
bulbs. Soon others followed suit.
Like a snowball rolling
downhill, bulb deflation grew at an increasingly rapid pace,
and in no time at all panic reigned.
Government ministers stated officially that there was no
reason for tulip bulbs to fall in price—but no one listened.
Dealers went bankrupt and refused to honor their
commitments to buy tulip bulbs. A government plan to settle
all contracts at 10 percent of their face value was frustrated
when bulbs fell even below this mark. And prices continued
to decline. Down and down
they went until most bulbs
became almost worthless—selling for no more than the price
of a common onion.
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: