. Does BB&T
requirements. Go to
www2.fdic.gov/qbp/
. This
Corporation. You will find summary data on finan-
cial institutions. Go to the most recent Quarterly
Banking Profile. Scroll down and open Table 1-A.
Financial Regulation
Preview
As we have seen in the previous chapters, the financial system is among the
most heavily regulated sectors of the economy, and banks are among the most
heavily regulated of financial institutions. In this chapter, we develop a frame-
work to see why regulation of the financial system takes the form it does.
Unfortunately, the regulatory process may not always work very well, as
evidenced by the recent 2007–2009 and other financial crises, not only in the
United States but in many countries throughout the world. Here we also use
our analysis of financial regulation to explain the worldwide crises in banking
and to consider how the regulatory system can be reformed to prevent
future disasters.
425
18
C H A P T E R
Asymmetric Information and Financial Regulation
In earlier chapters, we have seen how asymmetric information—the fact that dif-
ferent parties in a financial contract do not have the same information—leads to
adverse selection and moral hazard problems that have an important impact on our
financial system. The concepts of asymmetric information, adverse selection, and
moral hazard are especially useful in understanding why government has chosen
the form of financial regulation we see in the United States and in other countries.
There are nine basic categories of financial regulation: the government safety net,
restrictions on asset holdings, capital requirements, prompt corrective action, char-
tering and examination, assessment of risk management, disclosure requirements,
consumer protection, and restrictions on competition.
Government Safety Net
As we saw in Chapter 7, financial intermediaries, like banks, are particularly well suited
to solving adverse selection and moral hazard problems because they make private
loans that help avoid the free-rider problem. However, this solution to the free-rider
problem creates another asymmetric information problem, because depositors lack
information about the quality of these private loans. This asymmetric information prob-
lem leads to several reasons why the financial system might not function well.
Access
www.ny.frb.org/
banking/supervisionregulate
.html
to view bank
regulation information.
G O O N L I N E
426
Part 6 The Financial Institutions Industry
Bank Panics and the Need for Deposit Insurance
Before the FDIC started oper-
ations in 1934, a bank failure (in which a bank is unable to meet its obligations to
pay its depositors and other creditors and so must go out of business) meant that
depositors would have to wait to get their deposit funds until the bank was liquidated
(until its assets had been turned into cash); at that time, they would be paid only a frac-
tion of the value of their deposits. Unable to learn if bank managers were taking on
too much risk or were outright crooks, depositors would be reluctant to put money
in the bank, thus making banking institutions less viable. Second, depositors’ lack of
information about the quality of bank assets can lead to bank panics, which, as we
saw in Chapter 8, can have serious harmful consequences for the economy.
To see this, consider the following situation. There is no deposit insurance, and
an adverse shock hits the economy. As a result of the shock, 5% of the banks have
such large losses on loans that they become insolvent (have a negative net worth and
so are bankrupt). Because of asymmetric information, depositors are unable to tell
whether their bank is a good bank or one of the 5% that are insolvent. Depositors
at bad and good banks recognize that they may not get back 100 cents on the dol-
lar for their deposits and will want to withdraw them. Indeed, because banks oper-
ate on a “sequential service constraint” (a first-come, first-served basis), depositors
have a very strong incentive to show up at the bank first, because if they are last in
line, the bank may run out of funds and they will get nothing. Uncertainty about
the health of the banking system in general can lead to runs on banks both good
and bad, and the failure of one bank can hasten the failure of others (referred to as
the contagion effect). If nothing is done to restore the public’s confidence, a bank
panic can ensue.
Indeed, bank panics were a fact of American life in the nineteenth and early twen-
tieth centuries, with major ones occurring every 20 years or so in 1819, 1837, 1857,
1873, 1884, 1893, 1907, and 1930–1933. Bank failures were a serious problem even
during the boom years of the 1920s, when the number of bank failures averaged
around 600 per year.
A government safety net for depositors can short-circuit runs on banks and bank
panics, and by providing protection for the depositor, it can overcome reluctance
to put funds in the banking system. One form of the safety net is deposit insurance,
a guarantee such as that provided by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC) in the United States in which depositors are paid off in full on the first
$250,000 they have deposited in a bank if the bank fails. With fully insured deposits,
depositors don’t need to run to the bank to make withdrawals—even if they are
worried about the bank’s health—because their deposits will be worth 100 cents on
the dollar no matter what. From 1930 to 1933, the years immediately preceding the
creation of the FDIC, the number of bank failures averaged more than 2,000 per year.
After the establishment of the FDIC in 1934, bank failures averaged fewer than 15
per year until 1981.
The FDIC uses two primary methods to handle a failed bank. In the first, called
the payoff method, the FDIC allows the bank to fail and pays off deposits up to the
$250,000 insurance limit (with funds acquired from the insurance premiums paid
by the banks who have bought FDIC insurance). After the bank has been liquidated,
the FDIC lines up with other creditors of the bank and is paid its share of the pro-
ceeds from the liquidated assets. Typically, when the payoff method is used, account
holders with deposits in excess of the $250,000 limit get back more than 90 cents
on the dollar, although the process can take several years to complete.
In the second method, called the purchase and assumption method, the FDIC
reorganizes the bank, typically by finding a willing merger partner who assumes
Access
www.federalreserve
.gov/Regulations/default.htm
for regulatory
publications of the Federal
Reserve Board.
G O O N L I N E
Access
www.fdic.gov/bank/
historical/bank/index.html
to search for data on bank
failures in any year.
G O O N L I N E
Chapter 18 Financial Regulation
427
(takes over) all of the failed bank’s liabilities so that no depositor or other creditor
loses a penny. The FDIC often sweetens the pot for the merger partner by provid-
ing it with subsidized loans or by buying some of the failed bank’s weaker loans.
The net effect of the purchase and assumption method is that the FDIC has guar-
anteed all liabilities and deposits, not just deposits under the $250,000 limit. The pur-
chase and assumption method is typically more costly for the FDIC than the payoff
method, but nevertheless was the FDIC’s most common procedure for dealing with
a failed bank before new banking legislation in 1991.
In recent years, government deposit insurance has been growing in popularity
and has spread to many countries throughout the world. Whether this trend is desir-
able is discussed in the Global box, “The Spread of Government Deposit Insurance
Throughout the World: Is This a Good Thing?”
Other Forms of the Government Safety Net
Deposit insurance is not the only
form of government safety net. In other countries, governments have often stood
ready to provide support to domestic banks facing runs even in the absence of explicit
deposit insurance. Furthermore, banks are not the only financial intermediaries that
can pose a systemic threat to the financial system, as our discussion of financial crises
in Chapter 8 has illustrated. When financial institutions are very large or highly inter-
connected with other financial institutions or markets, their failure has the poten-
tial to bring down the entire financial system. Indeed, as we saw in Chapter 8, this
is exactly what happened with Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers, two investment
banks, and AIG, an insurance company, during the recent financial crisis in 2008.
One way governments provide support is through lending from the central bank
to troubled institutions, as the Federal Reserve did during the 2007–2009 financial
G L O B A L
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: