below its natural level. As prices
moving from point B to point C.
Finding modern examples to illustrate the lessons from Figure 9-12 is hard.
and they usually do their best to prevent that from happening. Fortunately,
history often fills in the gap when recent experience fails to produce the
right experiment.
A vivid example of the effects of monetary contraction occurred in
eighteenth-century France. François Velde, an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, recently studied this episode in French econom-
ic history.
The story begins with the unusual nature of French money at the time. The
money stock in this economy included a variety of gold and silver coins that,
in contrast to modern money, did not indicate a specific monetary value.
Instead, the monetary value of each coin was set by government decree, and
the government could easily change the monetary value and thus the money
supply. Sometimes this would occur literally overnight. It is almost as if, while
you were sleeping, every $1 bill in your wallet was replaced by a bill worth only
80 cents.
Indeed, that is what happened on September 22, 1724. Every person in
France woke up with 20 percent less money than they had the night before.
Over the course of seven months of that year, the nominal value of the money
stock was reduced by about 45 percent. The goal of these changes was to
reduce prices in the economy to what the government considered an appro-
priate level.
What happened as a result of this policy? Velde reports the following
consequences:
Although prices and wages did fall, they did not do so by the full 45 percent;
moreover, it took them months, if not years, to fall that far. Real wages in fact
rose, at least initially. Interest rates rose. The only market that adjusted instanta-
neously and fully was the foreign exchange market. Even markets that were as
close to fully competitive as one can imagine, such as grain markets, failed to
react initially. . . .
At the same time, the industrial sector of the economy (or at any rate the tex-
tile industry) went into a severe contraction, by about 30 percent. The onset of the
recession may have occurred before the deflationary policy began, but it was wide-
ly believed at the time that the severity of the contraction was due to monetary
policy, in particular to a resulting “credit crunch” as holders of money stopped pro-
viding credit to trade in anticipation of further price declines (the “scarcity of
money” frequently blamed by observers). Likewise, it was widely believed (on the
basis of past experience) that a policy of inflation would halt the recession, and
coincidentally or not, the economy rebounded once the nominal money supply
was increased by 20 percent in May 1726.
This description of events from French history fits well with the lessons from
modern macroeconomic theory.
4
■
C H A P T E R 9
Introduction to Economic Fluctuations
| 277
4
François R. Velde, “Chronicles of a Deflation Unforetold,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
November 2006.