C H A P T E R
6
Capital Allocation to Risky Assets
185
Higher indifference curves cor-
respond to higher levels of utility.
The investor thus attempts to find
the complete portfolio on the high-
est possible indifference curve.
When we superimpose plots of
indifference curves on the invest-
ment opportunity set represented
by the capital allocation line as
in
Figure 6.8
, we can identify the
highest possible indifference curve
that still touches the CAL. That
indifference curve is tangent to the
CAL, and the tangency point corre-
sponds to the standard deviation and
expected return of the optimal com-
plete portfolio.
To illustrate, Table 6.6 provides
calculations for four indifference
curves (with
utility levels of .07,
.078, .08653, and .094) for an inves-
tor with
A 5 4. Columns (2)–(5)
use Equation 6.8 to calculate the
expected return that must be paired
Figure 6.7
Indifference curves for U 5 .05 and U 5 .09 with A 5 2
and A 5 4
E(r)
0
U
= .09
A
= 4
A
= 4
A
= 2
A
= 2
U
= .05
.10
.20
.30
.40
.50
σ
.60
.40
.20
σ
c
= .0902
σ
P
= .22
σ
E(
r)
E(
r
P
)
= .15
E(
r
c
)
= .1028
r
f
= .07
C
P
CAL
0
U
= .094
U
= .08653
U
= .078
U
= .07
Figure 6.8
Finding the optimal complete portfolio by using indifference curves
bod61671_ch06_168-204.indd 185
bod61671_ch06_168-204.indd 185
6/18/13 8:08 PM
6/18/13 8:08 PM
Final PDF to printer
186
P A R T I I
Portfolio Theory and Practice
with the standard deviation in column (1) to provide the utility value corresponding to each
curve. Column (6) uses Equation 6.5 to calculate E ( r
C
) on the CAL for the standard devia-
tion s
C
in column (1):
E(
r
C
) 5 r
f
1
3E(r
P
) 2 r
f
4
s
C
s
P
5 7 1
315 2 74
s
C
22
Figure 6.8 graphs the four indifference curves and the CAL. The graph reveals that the
indifference curve with U 5 .08653 is tangent to the CAL; the tangency point corresponds
to the complete portfolio that maximizes utility. The tangency point occurs at s
C
5 9.02%
and E ( r
C
) 5 10.28%, the risk–return parameters of the optimal complete portfolio with
y * 5 0.41. These values match our algebraic solution using Equation 6.7.
We conclude that the choice for y *, the fraction of overall investment funds to place in
the risky portfolio, is determined by risk aversion (the slope of indifference curves) and the
Sharpe ratio (the slope of the opportunity set).
In sum, capital allocation determines the complete portfolio, which constitutes the
investor’s entire wealth. Portfolio P represents all-wealth-at-risk. Hence, when returns are
normally distributed, standard deviation is the appropriate measure of risk. In future chap-
ters we will consider augmenting P with “good” additions, meaning assets that improve
the feasible risk-return trade-off. The risk of these potential additions will have to be mea-
sured by their incremental effect on the standard deviation of P.
Nonnormal Returns
In the foregoing analysis we assumed normality of returns by taking the standard devia-
tion as the appropriate measure of risk. But as we discussed in Chapter 5, departures from
normality could result in extreme losses with far greater likelihood than would be plausible
under a normal distribution. These exposures, which are typically measured by value at
risk (VaR) or expected shortfall (ES), also would be important to investors.
Therefore, an appropriate extension of our analysis would be to present investors with
forecasts of VaR and ES. Taking the capital allocation from the normal-based analysis
as a benchmark, investors facing fat-tailed distributions might consider reducing their
allocation to the risky portfolio in favor of an increase in the allocation to the risk-free
vehicle.
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: