C H A P T E R
6
Capital Allocation to Risky Assets
183
This solution shows that the optimal position in the risky asset is inversely proportional
to the level of risk aversion and the level of risk (as measured by the variance) and directly
proportional to the risk premium offered by the risky asset.
Figure 6.6
Utility as a function of allocation to the risky asset, y
Utility
0
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Allocation to Risky Asset, y
0.8
1
1.2
.01
.02
.03
.04
.05
.06
.07
.08
.09
.10
A graphical way of presenting this decision problem is to use indifference curve
analysis. To illustrate how to build an indifference curve, consider an investor with
risk aversion A 5 4 who currently holds all her wealth in a risk-free portfolio yielding
Using our numerical example [ r
f
5 7%, E ( r
P
) 5 15%, and s
P
5 22%], and expressing all
returns as decimals, the optimal solution for an investor with a coefficient of risk aver-
sion A 5 4 is
y* 5
.15 2 .07
4 3 .22
2
5
.41
In other words, this particular investor will invest 41% of the investment budget in the
risky asset and 59% in the risk-free asset. As we saw in Figure 6.6 , this is the value of y
at which utility is maximized.
With 41% invested in the risky portfolio, the expected return and standard deviation
of the complete portfolio are
E(r
C
) 5 7 1
3.41 3 (15 2 7)4 5 10.28%
s
C
5
.41 3 22 5 9.02%
The risk premium of the complete portfolio is
E (
r
C
) 2 r
f
5 3.28%, which is obtained by
taking on a portfolio with a standard deviation of 9.02%. Notice that 3.28/9.02 = .36,
which is the reward-to-volatility (Sharpe) ratio of any complete portfolio given the
parameters of this example.
Example 6.4
Capital Allocation
bod61671_ch06_168-204.indd 183
bod61671_ch06_168-204.indd 183
6/18/13 8:08 PM
6/18/13 8:08 PM
Final PDF to printer
184
P A R T I I
Portfolio Theory and Practice
r
f
5 5%. Because the variance of such a portfolio is zero, Equation 6.1 tells us that its
utility value is U 5 .05. Now we find the expected return the investor would require
to maintain the same level of utility when holding a risky portfolio, say, with s 5 1%.
We use Equation 6.1 to find how much E ( r ) must increase to compensate for the higher
value of s :
U 5 E(r) 2 ½ 3 A 3 s
2
.05 5 E(r) 2 ½ 3 4 3 .01
2
This implies that the necessary expected return increases to
Required
E(
r) 5 .05 1 ½ 3
A 3 s
2
5 .05 1 ½ 3 4 3 .01
2
5 .0502
(6.8)
We can repeat this calculation for other levels of s , each time finding the value of E ( r )
necessary to maintain U 5 .05. This process will yield all combinations of expected return
and volatility with utility level of .05; plotting these combinations gives us the indifference
curve.
We can readily generate an investor’s indifference curves using a spreadsheet. Table 6.5
contains risk–return combinations with utility values of .05 and .09 for two investors, one
with A 5 2 and the other with A 5 4. The plot of these indifference curves appears in
Figure 6.7 . Notice that the intercepts of the indifference curves are at .05 and .09, exactly
the level of utility corresponding to the two curves.
Any investor would prefer a portfolio on the higher indifference curve with a higher cer-
tainty equivalent (utility). Portfolios on higher indifference curves offer a higher expected
return for any given level of risk. For example, both indifference curves for A 5 2 have
the same shape, but for any level of volatility, a portfolio on the curve with utility of .09
offers an expected return 4% greater than the corresponding portfolio on the lower curve,
for which U 5 .05.
Figure 6.7
demonstrates that more risk-averse investors have steeper indifference
curves than less risk-averse investors. Steeper curves mean that investors require a greater
increase in expected return to compensate for an increase in portfolio risk.
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: