C H A P T E R
2 4
Portfolio Performance Evaluation
855
24.4
Market Timing
In its pure form, market timing involves shifting funds between a market-index portfolio
and a safe asset, depending on whether the market index is expected to outperform the safe
asset. In practice, most managers do not shift fully between T-bills and the market. How
can we account for partial shifts into the market when it is expected to perform well?
To simplify, suppose that an investor holds only the market-index portfolio and T-bills.
If the weight of the market were constant, say, .6, then portfolio beta would also be con-
stant, and the SCL would plot as a straight line with slope .6, as in Figure 24.6, panel A .
If, however, the investor could correctly time the market and shift funds into it in periods
when the market does well, the SCL would plot as in Figure 24.6, panel B . If bull and bear
markets can be predicted, the investor will shift more into the market when the market
is about to go up. The portfolio beta and the slope of the SCL will be higher when r
M
is
higher, resulting in the curved line that appears in Figure 24.6, panel B .
Treynor and Mazuy were the first to propose estimating such a line by adding a squared
term to the usual linear index model:
19
r
P
2 r
f
5 a 1 b(r
M
2 r
f
)
1 c(r
M
2 r
f
)
2
1
e
P
where r
P
is the portfolio return, and a, b, and c are estimated by regression analysis.
If c turns out to be positive, we have evidence of timing ability, because this last term will
make the characteristic line steeper as r
M
2 r
f
is larger. Treynor and Mazuy estimated this
equation for a number of mutual funds, but found little evidence of timing ability.
A similar but simpler methodology was proposed by Henriksson and Merton.
20
These authors suggested that the beta of the portfolio take only two values: a large value
if the market is expected to do well and a small value otherwise. Under this scheme
the portfolio characteristic line appears as Figure 24.6, panel C . Such a line appears in
regression form as
r
P
2 r
f
5 a 1 b(r
M
2 r
f
)
1 c(r
M
2 r
f
)D
1 e
P
where D is a dummy variable that equals 1 for r
M
. r
f
and zero otherwise. Hence the beta
of the portfolio is b in bear markets and b 1 c in bull markets. Again, a positive value of c
implies market timing ability.
Henriksson
21
estimated this equation for 116 mutual funds. He found that the average
value of
c for the funds was
negative, and equal to 2.07. In sum, the results showed little
evidence of market timing ability. Perhaps this should be expected; given the tremendous
values to be reaped by a successful market timer, it would be surprising in nearly efficient
markets to uncover clear-cut evidence of such skills.
To illustrate a test for market timing, return to Table 24.2 . Regressing the excess returns
of portfolios P and Q on the excess returns of M and the square of these returns,
r
P
2 r
f
5 a
P
1 b
P
(r
M
2 r
f
)
1 c
P
(r
M
2 r
f
)
2
1
e
P
r
Q
2 r
f
5 a
Q
1 b
Q
(r
M
2 r
f
)
1 c
Q
(r
M
2 r
f
)
2
1
e
Q
19
Jack L. Treynor and Kay Mazuy, “Can Mutual Funds Outguess the Market?” Harvard Business Review 43
(July–August 1966).
20
Roy D. Henriksson and R. C. Merton, “On Market Timing and Investment Performance. II. Statistical Proce-
dures for Evaluating Forecast Skills,” Journal of Business 54 (October 1981).
21
Roy D. Henriksson, “Market Timing and Mutual Fund Performance: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of
Business 57 (January 1984).
bod61671_ch24_835-881.indd 855
bod61671_ch24_835-881.indd 855
7/25/13 3:13 AM
7/25/13 3:13 AM
Final PDF to printer