1 8 0
1
The First Dimension
of a Conservative
Investment
Superiority in Production, Marketing,
Research, and Financial Skills
A
corporation of the size and type to provide a conservative invest-
ment is necessarily a complex organization. To understand what
must be present in such an investment we might start by portray-
ing one dimension of the characteristics we must be sure exist. This
dimension breaks down into four major subdivisions:
LOW-COST PRODUCTION
To be a truly conservative investment a company—for a majority if not
for all of its product lines—must be the lowest-cost producer or about
as low a cost producer as any competitor. It must also give promise of
continuing to be so in the future. Only in this way will it give its own-
ers a broad enough margin between costs and selling price to create two
The First Dimension of a Conservative Investment
1 8 1
vital conditions. One is sufficient leeway below the break-even point of
most competition. When a bad year hits the industry, prices are unlike-
ly to stay for long under this break-even point. As long as they do, loss-
es for much of the higher-cost competition will be so great that some
of these competitors will be forced to cease production. This almost
automatically increases the profits of the surviving low-cost companies
because they benefit from the increased production that comes to them
as they take over demand formerly supplied by the closed plants. The
low-cost company will benefit even more when the decreased supply
from competitors enables it not only to do more business but also to
increase prices as excess supplies stop pressing on the market.
The second condition is that the greater than average profit margin
should enable a company to earn enough to generate internally a sig-
nificant part or perhaps all of the funds required for financing growth.
This avoids much or even all of the need for raising additional long-
term capital that can (a) result in new shares being issued and diluting
the value of already outstanding shares and/or (b) create an additional
burden of debt, with fixed interest payments and fixed maturities (which
must largely be met from future earnings) which greatly increase the
risks of the common-stock owners.
However, it should be realized that, just as the degree to which a
company is a low-cost producer increases the safety and conservatism of
the investment, so in a boom period in a bullish market does it decrease
its speculative appeal. The percentage that profits rise in such times will
always be far greater for the high-cost, risky, marginal company. Simple
arithmetic will explain why. Let us take an imaginary example of two
companies of the same size that, when times were normal, were selling
widgets at ten cents apiece. Company A has a profit of four cents per
widget and Company B of one cent. Now let us suppose that costs
remain the same but a temporary extra demand for widgets pushes up
the price to twelve cents, with both companies remaining the same size.
The strong company has increased profits from four cents per widget to
six cents, a gain of 50 percent, but the high-cost company has made a
300 percent profit gain, or tripled its profits. This is why, short-range, the
high-cost company sometimes goes up more in a boom and also why, a
few years later, when hard times come and widgets fall back to eight
cents, the strong company is still making a reduced but comfortable
profit. If the high-cost company doesn’t go bankrupt, it is likely to pro-
duce another crop of badly hurt investors (or perhaps speculators who
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |