Angus deaton



Download 0,78 Mb.
Pdf ko'rish
bet17/44
Sana11.01.2022
Hajmi0,78 Mb.
#349419
1   ...   13   14   15   16   17   18   19   20   ...   44
Bog'liq
casetextsp17bpea

Figure 17. 

Median Household Income by Race and Ethnicity, 1967–2015

Sources: Current Population Survey, March supplement; authors’ calculations. 

a. Note that this axis is nonlinear. 

Year

1970


1980

1990


2000

2010


2015 dollars

a

50,000



60,000

40,000


30,000

Whites 

White non-Hispanics 

Hispanics 

Blacks 


426

 

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2017

protective effects of income and education, even when both are allowed 

for together with controls for age, geography, and ethnicity. These studies 

attempt to control for the obviously important reverse effect of health on  

income by excluding those who are not in the labor force due to long-

term physical or mental illness, or by not using income in the period(s) 

before death. Even so, there are likely also effects that are not eliminated in 

this way, for example, those that operate through insults in childhood that 

impair both adult earnings and adult health. Nevertheless, it seems likely 

that income is protective of health, at least to some extent, even if it is over-

stated in the literature that does not allow for other factors.

There is a somewhat more contested body of literature on income 

and mortality at business cycle frequencies. Daniel Sullivan and Till von 

Wachter (2009) use administrative data to document the mortality effects 

of unemployment among high-seniority males; and Courtney Coile, Phillip 

Levine, and Robin McKnight (2014) note the vulnerability to unemploy-

ment of older, preretirement workers, who are unlikely to find new jobs and 

may be forced into early retirement, possibly without health insurance. The 

mortality effects that Coile, Levine, and McKnight (2014) and Sullivan and 

von Wachter (2009) document are not all instantaneous but are spread over 

many years, and are, in any case, much smaller than the effects that would be 

required to justify the results in figure 14 for those age 50–54. At the aggre-

gate level, unemployment cannot explain the mortality turnarounds in the 

post-2000 period; unemployment had recovered to its prerecession level by 

the end of the period, and was falling rapidly as mortality rose. It is of course 

possible that the aggregate is misleading, either because unemployment  

excludes discouraged workers, or because unemployment has not recov-

ered in the places where unemployment prompted mortality; for evidence 

linking mortality to trade-induced unemployment, see the work of Justin 

Pierce and Peter Schott (2016) and David Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon 

Hanson (2017).

There is, however, evidence against the unemployment story from Spain 

in research by Enrique Regidor and others (2016), who use individual-level 

data for the complete population of Spain to study mortality in the years 

2004–07 compared with 2008–11. In spite of the severity of the Great Reces-

sion in Spain, where unemployment rates rose from 8.2 percent in 2007 to 

21.4 percent in 2011, mortality was lower in the later period. This was true 

for most causes of death, including suicide, and for people of great or little  

wealth, approximately measured by floor space or car ownership in 2001, 

as well as for age groups 10–24, 25–49, and 50–74 taken separately.




ANNE CASE and ANGUS DEATON 

427


There is a venerable body of literature arguing that good times are bad 

for health, at least in the aggregate. As early as the work of William Ogburn 

and Dorothy Thomas (1922), it was noted that mortality in the United States 

was procyclical, with the apparently paradoxical finding that mortality 

rates are higher during booms than slumps. The result has been frequently 

but not uniformly confirmed in different times and places; perhaps the best-

known study in economics is by Christopher Ruhm (2000), who uses time 

series of states in the United States. More recently, Ruhm (2015) grapples 

with the same data as ours, and questions whether it remains true that reces-

sions are good for health. A frequent finding is that traffic fatalities are pro-

cyclical, as are the effects of pollution (Cutler, Huang, and Lleras-Muney  

2016). In contrast, suicides are often found to be countercyclical. Ann  

Stevens and others (2015) find that in the United States, many of the deaths 

in “good” times are among elderly women, and implicate the lower staffing 

levels in care facilities when labor is tight; procyclical deaths from influenza 

and pneumonia show up in several studies, again suggesting the importance 

of deaths among the elderly. To the extent that the positive macroeconomic  

relationship between mortality and income is driven by mortality among 

the elderly, it makes it easier to tell a story of income being protective 

among middle-aged groups, such as those on which we focus here.

Our own interpretation is that there is likely some genuine individual-

level positive effect of income on health, but that it is swamped by other 

macro factors in the aggregate. Of the results here, particularly those shown 

in figure 14, we suspect that the matching relationships are largely coinci-

dental, as has happened in other historical episodes.

The argument for coincidence is well illustrated by disaggregating the 

top panel of figure 14 by cause of death. As shown in section I, when we 

look at all-cause mortality, we need to think about deaths of despair (sui-

cides, overdoses, and alcoholism) together with heart disease. Deaths of 

despair have been rising at an accelerating rate since 1990; but, for a decade, 

they were offset by other declining causes of mortality, including heart 

disease. After 1999, the deaths of despair continued to rise, and they were 

now much larger, while the decline in heart disease slowed and eventually 

stopped, so that overall mortality started to go up. Both components are 

smooth trends, one rising and accelerating, the other falling but decelerat-

ing. Neither one in isolation has any relation to what has been happening to 

income; but together, they generate a turnaround that, by chance, coincides 

with the inverse U in family incomes. Spurious common Us are almost as  

easy to explain as spurious common trends.



428


Download 0,78 Mb.

Do'stlaringiz bilan baham:
1   ...   13   14   15   16   17   18   19   20   ...   44




Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©hozir.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling

kiriting | ro'yxatdan o'tish
    Bosh sahifa
юртда тантана
Боғда битган
Бугун юртда
Эшитганлар жилманглар
Эшитмадим деманглар
битган бодомлар
Yangiariq tumani
qitish marakazi
Raqamli texnologiyalar
ilishida muhokamadan
tasdiqqa tavsiya
tavsiya etilgan
iqtisodiyot kafedrasi
steiermarkischen landesregierung
asarlaringizni yuboring
o'zingizning asarlaringizni
Iltimos faqat
faqat o'zingizning
steierm rkischen
landesregierung fachabteilung
rkischen landesregierung
hamshira loyihasi
loyihasi mavsum
faolyatining oqibatlari
asosiy adabiyotlar
fakulteti ahborot
ahborot havfsizligi
havfsizligi kafedrasi
fanidan bo’yicha
fakulteti iqtisodiyot
boshqaruv fakulteti
chiqarishda boshqaruv
ishlab chiqarishda
iqtisodiyot fakultet
multiservis tarmoqlari
fanidan asosiy
Uzbek fanidan
mavzulari potok
asosidagi multiservis
'aliyyil a'ziym
billahil 'aliyyil
illaa billahil
quvvata illaa
falah' deganida
Kompyuter savodxonligi
bo’yicha mustaqil
'alal falah'
Hayya 'alal
'alas soloh
Hayya 'alas
mavsum boyicha


yuklab olish