A9/p9 Bourgeois Deeds


Give example from China book



Download 1,34 Mb.
bet5/24
Sana10.09.2017
Hajmi1,34 Mb.
#21897
1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   ...   24
Give example from China book. "In this consists the difference between the character of a miser," wrote Adam Smith in 1759, "and that of a [thrifty] person of exact economy and assiduity. The one is anxious about small matters for their own sake; the other attends to them only in consequence of the scheme of life which he has laid down for himself."169 Accumulate, accumulate is not a "scheme of life" in the ethical sense that Smith had in mind.

At the level of the society as a whole there is "unlimited" accumulation, at any rate if war and rapine and rats do not intervene. Corporations, having legally infinite lives—though in truth one in ten die every year—are to be sure sites of accumulation. The individual economic molecules who make up the river of innovation may not always want to accumulate beyond age 43, but the river as a whole, it is said, keeps rolling along. True, and to our good. The machines and improved acreage and splendid buildings and so forth inherited from an accumulating past are good for us now.

But there is no historical case for "accumulation, accumulation" being peculiar to capitalism. Old buildings are not novelties suddenly accumulated in the lifetime of modern capitalism. Infinitely lived institutions like families or churches or royal lineages existed before modern innovation, and were themselves, too, sites of accumulation. Thus improved acreage spread up the hillsides under the pressure of population before the Black Death. Thus the medieval cathedral were raised over centuries. Thus Oxford colleges were built, and endowed in real estate, itself the accumulated investment in drains and fencing and barns.

"The bourgeoisie," wrote Marx and Engels in 1848, "during its rule of scarce one hundred years has created more massive and colossal productive forces than have all the preceding generations together."170 It was a prescient remark. But the classical economists from Adam Smith to Marx were writing before the upsurge in real wages of British and Belgian and American working people in the last third of the nineteenth century, and long, long before the explosion of world income in the twentieth century. They imagined, I have noted, a moderate rise of income per person, perhaps at the most by a factor of two or three, such as might conceivably be achieved by Scotland's highlands becoming similar to capital-rich Holland (Smith's view) or by manufacturers in Manchester stealing savings from their poor workers (Marx's view) or by the savings generated from globalization being invested in European factories (John Stuart Mill's view). But the classical economists were mistaken.

The prehistory of thrift was revolutionized around 1960 when economists and economic historians realized with a jolt that thriftiness and savings could not explain the Industrial Revolution. The economists such as Solow and Abramowitz discovered that only a smallish fraction even of recent economic growth can be explained by thrift and accumulation. At the same time the economic historians were bringing the news that in Britain the rise in savings was too small to explain much at all. Simon Kuznets and later Charles Feinstein provided the rigorous accounting of the fact. It was anticipated in the 1950s and 1960s by numerous British economic historians, in detailed studies of banking and manufacturing. Peter Mathias summarized the case in 1973: "considerable revaluation has recently occurred in assessing the role of capital." 171 That is no overstatement.

The classical and mistaken view overturned by the economic historians of the 1950s and 1960s is that thrift implies saving which implies capital accumulation which implies modern economic growth. It lingered in a few works such as Walt Rostow's The Stages of Economic Growth (1960), and most unhappily in what William Easterly spelling?(2001) has called the "capital fundamentalism" of foreign aid, 1950 to the present. The belief was that if we give Ghana over several decades large amounts of savings, leading to massive capital investments in artificial lakes and Swiss bank accounts, and give Communist China not a penny, Ghana will prosper and Communist China will languish.172 Of course. The math tells us so. Unlike the actual event.

Chapter 4:

Nor Was It from Original Accumulation,

or the Protestant Ethic

We are back to what happened 1700-1848, and then on to 2000 and beyond, a rise of income per person by a factor by the end, let us say very conservatively, of 15. Once the happening was fully recognized, slowly in the twentieth century, it slowly killed the notion among most economists and economic historians that thrifty saving was the way to massive and colossal productive forces. In 1960 the economist Friedrich Hayek questioned “our habit of regarding economic progress chiefly as an accumulation of ever greater quantities of goods and equipment.”173

All right. Again: what then explains it?

New thoughts, what the economic historian Joel Mokyr calls the "industrial enlightenment." “The rise of our standard of living,” wrote Hayek, “is due at least as much to an increase in knowledge” as to accumulation of capital.174 It was ideas of steam engines and light bulbs and computers that made Northwestern Europe and then much of the rest of the world rich, not new accumulations from saving.175 Accumulation of physical capital is not the heart of modern innovation, as economic historians have understood since their researches of the 1950s and 1960s and as economists have understood since the calculations by Abramowitz and Solow in the 1950s, and before them the calculations by G. T. Jones in 1933.176 Its heart is innovation.

Of course, if you think up a waterpower-driven spinning machine you need some savings to bring the thought to fruition. But another of the discoveries of the 1960s by economic historians was that the savings required in England's heroic age of mechanization were modest indeed, nothing like the massive "original accumulation of capital" that Marxist theory posits. Early cotton factories were not capital-intensive. The source of the industrial investment required was short-term loans on inventories and loans from relatives—not savings ripped in great chunks from other parts of the economy.

The classical and Marxist idea that capital begets capital, "endlessly," is hard to shake. It has recently revived a little even among economists, in the form of so-called "new growth theory," an attempt to give M  C  M' a mathematically spiffed-up form. The trouble is that, as I have noted, savings and urbanization and state power to expropriate and the other physical-capital accumulations that are supposed to explain modern economic growth have existed on a large scale since the Sumerians. Attack agglomeration in ways I did in South Africa—disagglomeration, if it happened in Britain, which is very likely [indeed, almost necessary in the accounting]. Yet modern economic growth, that wholly unprecedented factor in the high teens, or 100 if quality of goods is measured properly, is a phenomenon of the past two centuries alone. Something happened in the eighteenth century that prepared for a temporary but shocking "great divergence" of the European economies from those of the rest of the world.177

The marxisant analysis is that what happened is the "original accumulation of capital." The original or primitive accumulation was according to Marx the seed corn, so to speak, or better the starter in the sourdough, in the growth of capital. We're back to thrift or savings, not by historical fact but by blackboard logic. "The whole movement," Marx reasoned, "seems to turn on a vicious circle, out of which we can only get by supposing a primitive accumulation, . . . an accumulation not the result of the capitalist mode of production, but its starting point."178 As the economic historian Alexander Gerschenkron put it in 1957, with characteristic sarcasm, it is "an accumulation of capital continuing over long historical periods—over several centuries—until one day the tocsin of the Industrial Revolution was to summon it to the battlefields of factory construction."179

Looking at the thrift necessary for an accumulation in a cheerful way, the starting point was a supposed rise of thriftiness among Dutch or especially English Puritans. Marx characterized such tales as praise for "that queer saint, that knight of the woeful countenance, the capitalist 'abstainer'."180 We can join him for a moment in disbelieving the optimistic tale, noting further, and contrary to his own pessimistic version of the same tale, as I have said, that abstention is universal. Saving rates in Catholic Italy or for that matter Confucian China were not much lower, if lower at all, than in Calvinist Massachusetts or Lutheran Germany. According to recent calculations, in fact, British investment in physical capital as a share of national income was strikingly below the European norm—only 4% in 1700, as against a norm of 11%, 6% as against 12% in 1760, and 8% against over 12% in 1800.181 Britain's investment, though rising before and then during the Industrial Revolution, showed less, not more, abstemiousness than in the less advanced countries around it. The evidence suggests, in other words, that saving depends on investment, not the other way around. When in the nineteenth century the rest of Europe started to follow Britain into industrialization, its savings rates rose, too. And the rest of Europe’s markedly higher rates during the eighteenth century did not cause it then to awaken from its medieval slumbers. Saving was not the constraint. As a great medieval economic historian, M. M. Postan, put it, it was not "the poor potential for saving" but the "extremely limited" character in pre-nineteenth-century Europe of "opportunities for productive investment."182

Marx's notion in Capital, on the contrary, was that an original accumulation was a sine qua non, and that there was no saintliness about it. The original accumulation was necessary because (Marx averred, mistakenly) masses of savings were necessary, and "conquest, enslavement, robbery, murder, briefly, force, play the greater part."183 He instanced enclosure in England during the sixteenth century (which has been overturned by historical findings that such enclosure was minor) and in the eighteenth (which has been overturned by findings that the labor driven off the land by enclosure was a tiny source of the industrial proletariat, and mainly in the south and east where in fact little of the new sort of industrialization was going on). He gave a large part then to regulation of wages in making a proletariat for the first time in the sixteenth century (which has been overturned by findings that half of the labor force in England as early as the thirteenth century already worked for wages; and that wage regulations did not work). And then to the slave trade: "Liverpool waxed fat on the slave-trade. This was its method of primitive accumulation" (which has been overturned by findings that the alleged profits were no massive fund).184 Later writers have proposed as the source of the original accumulation the exploitation by the core of the periphery (Poland, the New World).185 Or the influx of gold and silver from the New World—strange as it is then that imperial Spain did not industrialize. Or the exploitation of workers themselves during the Industrial Revolution, out of sequence. Or other loot from imperialisms old and new, too small to matter much. Or, following on Marx and Engels’ assertion in the Manifesto, even seventeenth-century piracy, tiny blips in the flow of treasure.

None of these, it has been found, make very much historical sense. The findings are in truth not very surprising. After all, conquest, enslavement, robbery, murder—briefly, violence—has characterized the sad annals of humankind since Cain and Abel. Why didn't earlier and even more thorough expropriations result in an Industrial Revolution and a factor of fifteen or twenty or whatever in the welfare of the average Briton or American or Taiwanese? Something besides thrifty self-discipline or violent expropriation must have been at work in northwestern Europe and its offshoots in the eighteenth century and later. Thrifty self-discipline and violent expropriation have been too common in human history to explain a revolution gathering force in Europe around 1800.

And as a practical matter a pile of physical capital financed from, say, Piet Heyn's seizure of the Spanish treasure fleet in 1628 would by 1800 melt away to nothing. It does not accumulate. It depreciates. And as Gerschenkron noted, “why should a long period of capital accumulation precede the period of rapid industrialization? Why is not the capital as it is being accumulated also invested in industrial ventures?” Why not indeed. In the story of original accumulation the clever capitalists are supposed to let their capital lie idle for centuries until the “tocsin” sounds.

The underlying confusion is between financial wealth in a bank account, which is merely a paper claim by this person against that person to the society's real wealth, on the one hand, and the society's real wealth in a house or ship or education, on the other. From the point of view of the society as a whole real wealth is what’s needed for real investment, not paper claims or gold coins You can't build a factory with pound notes, or dig a canal with bank accounts. You need bricks and wheelbarrows, and skilled people to wield them. Mere financing can hardly be the crux, or else the Catholic Church in 1300, with its dominate command of tokens of wealth, would have created an industrial society. Or Philip II—who after all was the principal beneficiary of those treasure fleets that the English and Dutch privateers preyed on—would have financed an Industrial Revolution in Spain.

Any original accumulation supposed to be useful to any real industrialization must be available in real things. But as the Holy Koran says, "what you possess [in real, physical things] will pass, but what is with God will abide" (16:96). "These lovely [earthly] things" wrote St. Augustine, "go their way and are no more. . . . In them is no repose, because they do not abide."186 A real house made in 1628 out of Piet's profit would be tumbled down by 1800, unless in the meantime its occupants had continued to invest in it. A real educated person of 1628 would be long dead, a real machine would be obsolete, a real book would be eaten by worms. The force of depreciation makes an original accumulation spontaneously disappear.

This is not to say, note well, that conquest, enslavement, robbery, and murder play no part in European history. A Panglossian assumption that contract, not force, explains, say, the relation between lord and peasant defaces the recent work on "new" institutionalism, such as that of Douglass North.187 But, pace Marx, modern economic growth did not and does not and cannot depend on the scraps to be gained by stealing from poor people. Stealing from poor people, when you think about it, could hardly explain enrichment by a factor of fifteen. Would you do so well by robbing the homeless people in your neighborhood, or by breaking into the home of the average factory worker? Would grabbing stuff from the poor of the world enrich the average person in the world, including those poor themselves, by a factor of eight-and-a-half or nine since 1800? Does it strike you as plausible that British national income depended much on stealing from an impoverished India? If it did, why did real income per head in Britain go up sharply in the decade after Britain "lost" India? So all the imperial powers after 1945: France, Holland, Portugal, Belgium.

Modern economic growth has not depended on saving, and therefore has not depended on stealing to get the saving. Turgot and Smith and Mill and Marx got the story entirely wrong. That they got it wrong is unsurprisingly considering the stately pace at which the economies they were looking at were improving, at least by contrast with the frenetic pace after 1848 and especially after 1948, and then most of all after 1978. The early economists had a theory of modest modernization to the level of the Netherlands in 1776, not a transformation to a level of suburban America in 2010. "All the authors [who] followed the Turgot-Smith line," wrote Schumpeter as the frenzy was becoming apparent, "[were] at fault in believing that thrift was the all-important (causal) factor."188 Most savings for innovation, Schumpeter had noted twenty years earlier, "does not come from thrift in the strict sense, that is from abstaining from consumption. . . but [from] funds which are themselves the result of successful innovation" (in the language of accounting, "retained earnings").189 The money for any massive innovation—as against the savings in the strict sense—comes, he argues, from banks using "money creation." (The somewhat mysterious phrase “money creation” means simply the loans beyond the gold in their vaults that venturing bankers can make, on the supposition that not everyone wants their gold back at the same time. In a word, it is credit.)

But Schumpeter did not fully appreciate that even in the twentieth century of wide markets and big laboratories a company like Google can expand without any bank loans at all, rather in the way that the first innovations of the Industrial Revolution relied on retained earnings, trade credit, and modest loans from cousins and scriveners and solicitors—not the massive public offerings required 1840-1940 by capital-intensive industries like railways, steel, chemicals, automobiles, electricity generation, and oil exploration and refining. The episode 1840-1940 of capital intensity is another reason for the capital fundamentalism of economics one sees in economics even now. Economics grew up as a science in the Age of Capital, as the historian Eric Hobsbawm called it. Naturally the economists such as Mill or Marx or Marshall became obsessed with accumulation. But as Hobsbawm and other historical materialists who have long lamented the “predominance of [physical, factory] capital” did not sufficiently appreciate (though employed in the industry supplying education), 1840-1940 became an age increasingly of human capital.190 By now in rich countries the returns to human capital account for a much higher share of national income than do the returns to land and especially machinery that so exercised the very first generation of economic historians, contemporaries of Marx.

In other words, early in modern economic growth, and now again late, the moving frontier of best practice has depended mainly on innovation, not thrift. The outcome has depended on the invention of entirely new ways of propelling ships or making shoes. And nowadays it depends, if your country is as Gerschenkron put it, "relatively backward," on leaping over the slow early stages of invention and investment by adopting what has already been invented, getting now cell phones instead of laboriously investing in land-lines and then laboriously inventing substitutes. Money creation, or the 50 percent savings rates in present-day China, can finance the leaping. And money creation in any moderately well run economy is routinely available. It is simply a capitalized belief in the future, and again that assurance that not everyone will run to the bank today. It has become routine in one country after another since capital markets took root, from goldsmiths in Florence to venture capitalists in San Jose, not to speak of fourth century B.C.E Greece or medieval China.191 When the beliefs break down, a crisis occurs. But the lurching progress of capitalism has never been seriously in doubt since around 1800. Well, for a time during the Great Depression it was—but the doubt was followed after the War by the greatest capitalist boom so far.

What was not routinely available in the eighteenth century was the great stock of inventions available now, including the institutional inventions allowing cooperation by masses of people without the knout and sword. This is why China and India can now grow at rates inconceivable in the eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, before the inventions were well launched.

One must take care. Joseph Needham and his sinologist colleagues have shown in the past fifty years that the Chinese were in fact astoundingly inventive for millennia before the West caught the bug. (One awaits a similar demonstration for the Indians: cotton cloth, systematic grammar.) The West did not know how much it owed, or in what ways it was anticipated, commonly by many hundreds of years. And in the face of Western hubris the Chinese forgot their pioneering, until Needham’s labors. Robert Temple has written an engaging popular exposition of Needham’s 24 stout volumes. He gives a table of 110 inventions anticipated by the Chinese, and often used on a large scale. We all know about paper, invented and in common use in China in the second century B.C.E. (though not used for writing until the first century C.E.) but not manufactured in the West until the thirteenth century C.E., a lag of 1500 years, or the compass, invented and in common use in China in the fourth century B.C.E. (though not used for sea navigation until the late first millennium C.E.) but not adopted in the West until the twelfth century C.E., a lag again of 1500 years.192 About the gun the Westerners were more urgently curious, and the lag was only 50 years after its invention in China in 1180 C.E. An economist would know of paper money, too, with a lag of 850 years until the clever Westerners thought to use it. An agricultural historian might have known that the iron-share, curved-moldboard plow, invented by the Chinese 500 years before Christ came from China to Holland in the seventeenth century, and thence to England. But few could have known before Needham that the Chinese invented the seed drill 1800 years before its use in the West, the crank handle 1100 years before, deep-drilling for natural gas 1900 years, the wheelbarrow 1300 years, a place for zero in a decimal system 1400 years, and knowledge of the circulation of blood 1800 years before Harvey.

Needham’s work established the now-accepted truth that up until about 1700 there was little to distinguish European from Chinese (or Japanese or Indian or Ottoman) technology. The recent lead of Europe was not ancient. Needham and collaborators have shown that a claim for European innovation stretching back to the tenth century is false. True, the Europeans invented by themselves in the Middle Ages windmills to grind grain and fulling mills to thicken wool cloth, and perfected the mechanical clock (invented eighth century C.E. in China, says Needham, but not until 1310 by the Europeans, having heard of the Chinese machine), and invented eye glasses, and dubiously independently invented cast iron in Sweden—though long after the Chinese, and using exactly the design of furnace, funnily enough, used in China in the century before.193 But the Europeans had to learn from the Chinese gradually, starting in the late first millennium, the stirrup, horse collar, printing, multiple-masted fore-and-after rigging. In the early seventeenth century, Needham writes, “Francis Bacon had selected three inventions, paper and printing, gunpowder, and the magnetic compass, which had done more, he thought, than any religious conviction, or any astrological influence, or any conqueror’s achievement, to transform completely the modern world. . . . All of them were Chinese.”194

But Needham’s work shows something else, which he emphasized and which is most relevant to our story here. The Europeans in a rising wave of creativity from the seventeenth century stole, copied, adopted, improved, extended, reverse-engineered, and above all applied what they had learned from the Chinese, and from anyone else they chanced to meet on their fanatical peregrinations: coffee from the Ethiopians via the Ottomans, potatoes from the Incas. Meanwhile in the centuries before 1800 the Chinese (and the Japanese) were fatally satisfied with their own panoply. Needham argues that the “relentless experimentation” that overcame Europe c. 1700 was “like the merchant’s standard of value.” And merchants came to rule.

Why the difference? The Chinese invention of bureaucracy beginning with the First Emperor (207 B.C.E.) was preceded by imperial administrations in the ancient Near East, and reinvented by the Europeans as the imperial notion of Alexander’s and Caesar’s descendents in the Mediterranean, and then re-invented by the European nation state in the sixteenth and especially the seventeenth centuries C.E. and later. The point was to subordinate everyone to the emperor/king by robbing a senatorial class or a feudal aristocracy of its separate power. Centralization on the scale of the whole of Europe had precursors in the bureaucracy of the Church, copied from that of the Roman Empire. But later and secular versions could not be sustained, despite the efforts of Charlemagne, Phillip II, Napoleon, and Hitler, at any rate until the peaceful conquests in our own times of the treaties of Rome and Maastricht. The Chinese version, by contrast, was thorough and continuous, “a civil service unimaginable in extent and degree of organization to the petty kingdoms of Europe.”195 Chinese economic history can therefore be investigated with a wealth of statistics unimaginable in Europe until the statistical age after 1800.196

The Chinese bureaucracy, Needham argues, “in its early stages strongly helped science to grow,” albeit sometimes for such purposes as accurately casting the horoscopes of the emperor’s fourth son. But in its later stages, just as the Europeans learned to use such Chinese inventions as the belt drive, the suspension bridge, the spinning wheel, decimal fractions, the canal pound-lock, and sea mines, and indeed the examination bureaucracy itself, the bureaucracy “forcibly inhibit[ed] further growth, and in particularly prevented a break-through which has occurred in Europe.” European-style centralized states have done similar work in the twentieth century, forcibly if often democratically inhibiting growth in a protectionist New Zealand or a populist Argentina or an authoritarian North Korea.

The results of the compounding of ancient Chinese (and Arab and Ottoman and Inca and African) inventions with modern European creativity lie around you right now—computers, electric lights, electric machinery, precision tooling, plastic printers, plastic fabrics, telephones, pressed wood, plywood, plaster-board, plate glass, steel framing, reinforced concrete, automobiles, machine-woven carpets, central heating and cooling, all invented in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries in a Europe that practiced science and innovation with an almost insane enthusiasm, and had no emperor to gainsay the practices. Therefore England in the eighteenth century could not possibly have experienced the present-day Chinese growth rate of real income per head of 10 percent per year, even in its greatest booms. The doubling in a mere seven years that such a rate implies could not happen before very recent times, with gigantic piles of the already-invented waiting to be adopted. Invent paper or cast iron slowly over many centuries as you will, it’s not enough for the break-through. What’s needed, writes Madame Chen Zhili, State Councilor of China for Education, Science, Technology, and Culture in a preface Temple’s popularization of Needham, is “innovation [which] is the spirit of a nation and the endless momentum for a nation’s prosperity.”197

China and India can take off the shelf the inventions laboriously developed by the Watts and the Edisons of the past three centuries, and by the Chinese and Indian inventors of earlier centuries whose inventions had been taken up eagerly by the now curious Westerners. Indians invent fine cotton cloth, which then becomes the staple of Manchester, but latterly in its mechanized form the staple of Mumbai. The Chinese invent cast iron, which then becomes the staple of Sweden and English Cleveland and American Gary, but latterly in its chemically engineered form the staple of


Download 1,34 Mb.

Do'stlaringiz bilan baham:
1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   ...   24




Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©hozir.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling

kiriting | ro'yxatdan o'tish
    Bosh sahifa
юртда тантана
Боғда битган
Бугун юртда
Эшитганлар жилманглар
Эшитмадим деманглар
битган бодомлар
Yangiariq tumani
qitish marakazi
Raqamli texnologiyalar
ilishida muhokamadan
tasdiqqa tavsiya
tavsiya etilgan
iqtisodiyot kafedrasi
steiermarkischen landesregierung
asarlaringizni yuboring
o'zingizning asarlaringizni
Iltimos faqat
faqat o'zingizning
steierm rkischen
landesregierung fachabteilung
rkischen landesregierung
hamshira loyihasi
loyihasi mavsum
faolyatining oqibatlari
asosiy adabiyotlar
fakulteti ahborot
ahborot havfsizligi
havfsizligi kafedrasi
fanidan bo’yicha
fakulteti iqtisodiyot
boshqaruv fakulteti
chiqarishda boshqaruv
ishlab chiqarishda
iqtisodiyot fakultet
multiservis tarmoqlari
fanidan asosiy
Uzbek fanidan
mavzulari potok
asosidagi multiservis
'aliyyil a'ziym
billahil 'aliyyil
illaa billahil
quvvata illaa
falah' deganida
Kompyuter savodxonligi
bo’yicha mustaqil
'alal falah'
Hayya 'alal
'alas soloh
Hayya 'alas
mavsum boyicha


yuklab olish