147
expectations are liable to disappointment and expectations concerning the future affect what we do
to-day. It is when we have made this transition that the peculiar properties of money as a link
between the present and the future must enter into our calculations. But, although the theory of
shifting equilibrium must necessarily be pursued in terms of a monetary economy,
it remains a
theory of value and distribution and not a separate 'theory of money'. Money in its significant
attributes is, above all, a subtle device for linking the present to the future; and we cannot even
begin to discuss the effect of changing expectations on current activities except in monetary terms.
We cannot get rid of money even by abolishing gold and silver and legal tender instruments. So
long as there exists any durable asset, it is capable of possessing monetary attributes and, therefore,
of giving rise to the characteristic problems of a monetary economy.
II
In a single industry its particular price-level depends partly on the rate of remuneration of the
factors of production which enter into its marginal cost, and partly on the scale of output. There is
no reason to modify this conclusion when we pass to industry as a whole. The general price-level
depends partly on the rate of remuneration of the factors of production which enter into marginal
cost and partly on the scale of output as a whole, i.e. (taking equipment and technique as given) on
the volume of employment. It is true that, when
we pass to output as a whole, the costs of
production in any industry partly depend on the output of other industries. But the more significant
change, of which we have to take account, is the effect of changes in
demand
both on costs and on
volume. It is on the side of demand that we have to introduce quite new ideas when we are dealing
with demand as a whole and no longer with the demand for a single product taken in isolation, with
demand as a whole assumed to be unchanged.
III
If we allow ourselves the simplification of assuming that the rates of remuneration of the different
factors of production which enter into marginal cost all change in the same proportion, i.e. in the
same proportion as the wage-unit, it follows that the general price-level (taking equipment and
technique as given) depends partly on the wage-unit and partly on the volume of employment.
Hence the effect of changes in the quantity of money on the price-level can be considered as being
compounded of the effect on the wage-unit and the effect on employment.
To
elucidate the ideas involved, let us simplify our assumptions still further, and assume (1) that all
unemployed resources are homogeneous and interchangeable in their efficiency to produce what is
wanted, and (2) that the factors of production entering into marginal cost are content with the same
money-wage so long as there is a surplus of them unemployed. In this case we have constant returns
and a rigid wage-unit, so long as there is any unemployment. It follows that an increase in the
quantity of money will have no effect whatever on prices, so long as there is any unemployment,
and that employment will increase in exact proportion to any increase in effective demand brought
about by the increase
in the quantity of money; whilst as soon as full employment is reached, it will
thenceforward be the wage-unit and prices which will increase in exact proportion to the increase in
effective demand. Thus if there is perfectly elastic supply so long as there is unemployment, and
perfectly inelastic supply so soon as full employment is reached, and if effective demand changes in
the same proportion as the quantity of money, the quantity theory of money can be enunciated as
follows: 'So long as there is unemployment,
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: