Th
is gives the classic ‘U’ shape to the ATC curve. On a
graph of cost data, the MC will always cross AVC and
ATC at their lowest points. In this situation, the most
effi
cient output for the fi rm will be where the unit cost
is lowest. Th
is is known as the optimum output. It is
where the fi rm is productively effi
cient in the short run;
the most effi
cient output is not necessarily the most
profi table since profi t maximisation may only be possible
in the long run. For a fi rm wishing to maximise its
profi ts, its chosen output will depend on the relationship
between its revenue and its costs.
TOP TIP
Decision making by firms is very dependent upon
marginal cost. The significance of this will become clear
in the rest of this chapter.
From short-run to long-run
As stated above, the short run is a period of time in
Economics when at least one of the factors of production
is fi xed. Th
e factor that tends to be easiest to change is
labour as we have already seen. Th
e factor that takes
longest to change is capital. Students oft en ask the
question, ‘How long is the short run?’ Th
is is not an
easy question to answer, as it tends to diff er for diff erent
industries. In the clothing industry it is likely to be no
more than a few weeks: the time that is taken to install
new machines and to get these operational to produce
clothing. In other industries, it will be much longer. A
country building a new hydroelectric power station will,
for example, take much longer to plan, install and make
such a new facility operational. Ten years may well be a
realistic estimate in this case. Th
is time is still referred
to as the short run since capital is fi xed over this time.
So, the short run is
not
defi ned in terms of a specifi c
period of time; it refers to the time when not all factors of
production are variable.
All factors of production are variable in the long
run. Th
is gives the fi rm much greater scope to vary the
respective mix of its factor inputs so that it is producing
at the most effi
cient level. So if capital becomes relatively
cheaper than labour or if a new production process is
invented and this increases productivity then fi rms can
reorganise the way in which they produce. Firms must
therefore know the cost of the factors of production they
use and see this in relation to the additional product that
accrues. Knowing costs is quite easy in the case of labour
and some other basic inputs; it is more diffi
cult to estimate
for other factors of production. Th
e best combination of
factors can be arrived at as their price varies. Firms should
aim to be in a position where:
marginal product marginal product marginal product
factor A
price of facto
ff
r A
factor B
price of facto
ff
r B
factor C
price of
=
=
factor
ff
C
and so on for all factors of production they use. For them to
be able to do this all factors of production must be variable.
If we go back to the principles introduced in
Figure 7.6,
it is possible to derive the long-run production function
for a fi rm by initially constructing an isoquant map. Th
is
shows the diff erent combinations of labour and capital
that can be used to produce various level of output. Th
is is
shown in
Figure 7.9.
Let us again assume that this is for a clothing
manufacturer.
Figure 7.9a
consists of a collection of
isoquants for output levels of 100, 200, 300, 400 and
500 units of production. From this it is possible to read
off the respective combinations of labour and capital that
Labour
0
Capital
Labour
0
Capital
Long-run production function
500
400
300
200
100
(a) Isoquant map
(b) Long-run production function
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: