186
The record of government planning in different countries illustrates this point.
It is fraught with conflicts and internal inconsistencies:
The federal government of the United States pays some farmers not to produce grain
products, and at the same time, provides others with subsidized
irrigation projects so
they can grow more of the very same grain products. Similar European Union subsidies
have resulted in
surplus
(?)
production of many agricultural products, leading to the
popular expression “butter mountain.”
United States government programs for dairy farmers keep the price of milk high,
while government subsidizes the school lunch program
to make the expensive milk
more affordable.
India’s food subsidy program tries to benefit consumers as well as producers. As a
result, India has accomplished the extraordinary feat of rationing grain to consumers at
artificially low prices, while simultaneously suffering excess supply, because farmers
are paid high prices. (Farmers are also subsidized via agricultural inputs—electricity,
water, and fertilizer—to the detriment of the environment.) The government has
purchased huge stockpiles of rotting rice and wheat, while the limited amount available
to consumers is allocated in ways that are corrupt and inconsistent with the stated goal
of helping the poor.
(79)
Around the world, countries spend $30 billion a year on fisheries subsidies, 60 percent
of which directly stimulates unsustainable, destructive practice. In 2012, the resulting
market distortion had a cost of $83 billion to the global economy.
(80)
In 2015 and 2016, the G7 governments gave at least $81 billion in fiscal support and
$20 billion in public finance each year for production and consumption of oil, gas, and
coal, while simultaneously extensively subsidizing wind and solar energy production.
In 2019, the United Kingdom was expected to spend €12bn in support of fossil fuels,
and €8.3bn in support of competing renewable energy sources.
Returning to India, a Comprehensive Action Plan to deal with pollution prepared by the
Environment Pollution Control Authority (EPCA) says
that Compressed Natural Gas
(CNG) should not be promoted because it “is one of the major contributors of Nitrous
187
Oxides and is also expected to increase Particulate Matter (PM1) in the air.” This
position is in direct opposition to the Central Pollution Control Board’s 42-point Action
Plan (2015) for Delhi, which required the city to indicate how it would begin to shift
public transport to a CNG mode as rapidly as possible.
In general, conflicting policies result from a fundamental tension between on the one
hand a system of market regulation that aims to put citizens and productivity in charge of the
economy and on the other a system of governmental rigging of the economy to benefit
politically favored sectors and firms.
Economic analysis indicates that extensive use of government planning will lead to
both economic inefficiency and cronyism. When government officials decide what is bought
and sold, or the prices of those items, the first thing that will be bought and sold will be the
votes of elected officials. When enterprises get more funds from governments and less from
consumers, they will spend more time trying to influence politicians
and less time trying to
reduce costs and please customers. Predictably, the substitution of politics for markets will lead
to economic regression and, in the words of Ukrainian born economist Ludwig Von Mises,
“The worst evils which mankind has ever had to endure were inflicted
by bad
governments.”
(81)