Investment for the Long Run
Now we turn to the implications of risk pooling and risk sharing for long-term investing.
Think of extending an investment horizon for another period (which adds the uncertainty
of that period’s risky return) as analogous to adding another risky asset or insurance policy
to a pool of assets.
Examining the impact of an extension of the investment horizon requires us to clarify
what the alternative is. Suppose you consider an investment in a risky portfolio over the
next 2 years, which we’ll call the “long-term investment.” How should you compare this
decision to a “short-run investment”? We must compare these two strategies over the same
period, that is, 2 years. The short-term investment therefore must be interpreted as invest-
ing in the risky portfolio over 1 year and in the risk-free asset over the other.
Once we agree on this comparison, and assuming the risky return on the first year is
uncorrelated with that of the second, it becomes clear that the “long-term” strategy is
analogous to portfolio Z. This is because holding on to the risky investment in the sec-
ond year (rather than withdrawing to the risk-free rate) piles up more risk, just as selling
another insurance policy does. Put differently, the long-term investment may be considered
analogous to risk pooling. While extending a risky investment to the long run improves the
Sharpe ratio (as does risk pooling), it also increases risk. Thus “time diversification” is not
really diversification.
The more accurate analogy to risk sharing for a long-term horizon is to spread the risky
investment budget across each of the investment periods. Compare the following three
strategies applied to the whole investment budget over a 2-year horizon:
1. Invest the whole budget at risk for one period, and then withdraw the entire
proceeds, placing them in a risk-free asset in the other period. Because you
are invested in the risky asset for only 1 year, the risk premium over the whole
investment period is R, the 2-year SD is s , and the 2-year Sharpe ratio is
S 5 R / s .
2. Invest the whole budget in the risky asset for both periods. The 2-year risk premium
is 2 R (assuming continuously compounded rates), the 2-year variance is 2 s
2
, the
2-year SD is s
"2, and the 2-year Sharpe ratio is S 5 R"2/s. This is analogous to
risk pooling, taking two “bets” on the risky portfolio instead of one (as in Strategy 1).
3. Invest half the investment budget in the risky position in each of two periods, plac-
ing the remainder of funds in the risk-free asset. The 2-year risk premium is R,
bod61671_ch07_205-255.indd 233
bod61671_ch07_205-255.indd 233
6/18/13 8:11 PM
6/18/13 8:11 PM
Final PDF to printer
Visit us at www
.mhhe.com/bkm
234
P A R T I I
Portfolio Theory and Practice
the 2-year variance is 2 3 (½ s )
2
5 s
2
/2, the SD is s/
"2, and the Sharpe ratio is
S
5 R"2/s. This is analogous to risk sharing, taking a fractional position in each
year’s investment return.
Strategy 3 is less risky than either alternative. Its expected total return equals Strategy 1’s,
yet its risk is lower and therefore its Sharpe ratio is higher. It achieves the same Sharpe
ratio as Strategy 2 but with standard deviation reduced by a factor of 2. In summary, its
Sharpe ratio is at least as good as either alternative and, more to the point, its total risk is
less than either.
We conclude that risk does not fade in the long run. An investor who can invest in an
attractive portfolio for only one period, and chooses to invest a given budget in that period,
would find it preferable to put money at risk in that portfolio in as many periods as allowed
but will decrease the risky budget in each period. Simple risk pooling, or in this case, time
diversification, does not reduce risk.
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |