116 PART 2 SUPPLY AND DEMAND: HOW MARKETS WORK
How Changes in Income Affect the Consumer’s Choices
Suppose that income increases. We know that if income increases there is a parallel shift of the budget
constraint with the same slope of the initial budget line because the relative price of the two goods has
not changed.
The increase in income means there is an incentive for the consumer to reallocate his spending
decisions to increase utility and choose a better combination of cola and pizza. In other words, the con-
sumer can now reach a higher indifference curve as shown in Figure 5.12. The consumer reallocates
income until he reaches a new optimum labelled ‘new optimum’.
Notice that in Figure 5.12 the consumer chooses to consume more cola and more pizza. Although
the logic of the model does not require increased consumption of both goods in response to increased
income, this situation is the most common one. Remember, if a consumer wants more of a good when
his income rises, economists call it a normal good. The indifference curves in Figure 5.12 are drawn under
the assumption that both cola and pizza are normal goods.
Figure 5.13 shows an example in which an increase in income induces the consumer to buy more pizza
but less cola. If a consumer buys less of a good when his income rises, economists call it an inferior good.
Figure 5.13 is drawn under the assumption that pizza is a normal good and cola is an inferior good.
shirts (I probably did not need one shirt) and if I was being asked to hand over
€60 for the item regardless
of how many shirts, I may not have made the decision to spend that much money. If I was never going to
spend it then it is not a saving. Many consumers, however, do tell their friends that they ‘saved’ lots as a
result of their trip, despite these facts. Psychologists call it confirmation bias.
There is also research which shows that far from being rational in our decision making when shopping,
we can be deeply irrational. Our brains react differently to information we see when we are shopping and
retailers know this. On the one hand we are primed when we go shopping. Psychologists have shown
that when humans are given information which creates an association they are more likely to behave in
ways which confirm the association. If the brain is primed to look for bargains or offers we are more likely
to make a purchase decision when confronted with information which seems to represent a ‘bargain’.
If prices are lower than anticipated then the decision making part of the brain registers this and we are
more likely to make the purchase as a result. Equally, if prices are much higher than anticipated a different
part of the brain associated with registering pain is activated and we avoid the purchase.
Overall, therefore, whilst our model of consumer behaviour provides some insights, as with any model
it is a representation of reality and not reality itself. There is now a great deal of research being conduc-
ted which is shedding more light on consumer behaviour which casts doubt on just how rational we are
capable of being.
Many stores provide
information on their receipt
or online order form telling
consumers how much they
have ‘saved’ as a result of
their purchase decisions
CHAPTER 5 BACKGROUND TO DEMAND: THE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE
117
Although most goods are normal goods, there are some inferior goods in the world. One example is
bus rides. High-income consumers are more likely to own cars and less likely to ride the bus than low-in-
come consumers. Bus rides, therefore, are an inferior good.
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: