1 8
priorities and conditions, and the pool of common
knowledge (
Fig. 1
). Goals and conditions can
vary widely among decision-makers. It is worth
distinguishing between individual operators
(farmers) and public administrators, who often
have very different points of view, capacity and
freedom of intervention. The latter have in mind
social, macroeconomic, environmental goals (e.g.
hydrogeological, erosion, pollution, eutrofication
problems); they can apply conditions, constraints,
incentives etc. to individual operators. These, by
contrast, pursue a set of priorities, the economic
ones usually prevailing. In general most practical
interventions in agriculture are dictated by the
needs of the individual operators within the ambits
of material and non-material constraints (including
those imposed by the authorities) and as suggested
by systematic (extension services, advertizing,
mass media), or uncertain (e.g. meteorological
events, market price variations etc.) external
inputs. Increasing economic competition and
market globalization demand more freedom in
decisions, more flexibility from equipment and
work programmes, as well as a set of rules to fo-
llow in the case of unfavourable events and a
damping system to face fluctuating results. Any
decision to be taken implies an adequate
knowledge of the system on which to operate. In
practice the available knowledge far from satisfies
the need for rationality of decisions and this is
especially true for tillage problems (one of the
least rationalized agronomic practices). Usually
much has still to be done to suit the many
suggested tillage and cropping management
packages to the real conditions, where many
parameters are not adequately known and inputs
(especially meteorological ones) occur
unexpectedly (say a rainy period at time of
seeding) or are e xpected on a probability basis
(future weather patterns).
After the results of a given tillage operation or
set of interventions are examined, the decision-
makers involved (both individual and public)
evaluate whether and to what extent the
proposed goal (say profit or simply yield) has
set of interventions are examined, the decision-
makers involved (both individual and public)
evaluate whether and to what extent the
proposed goal (say profit or simply yield) has
been reached; they also appraise any side-effects
(e.g. quality traits, by-products), both unexpected or
expected with a given probability (e.g. interactions with
meteorological events); often a side-effect is not easily
detected or might become evident after a long time e.g.
decades (long-term change in fertility; erosion damage;
environmental pollution). Note (a) the possible contrast
between the judgement of individual and public decision -
makers and (b) the possible surprise after detection of
favourable or unfavourable side-effects (this has often been
the case for environmental effects or long-term soil fertility
variations). As a rule e xamination of the results leads to
improved knowledge (learning process), a revision of
decision criteria and eventually modification of goals.
Compared to what has been said above, the usual
recommendations for "best farm management" appear
too generalized and do not adequately help to face events,
costs and risks, nor are they flexible and sufficiently site
and condition specific.
In any case a decision-maker, especially at the farm level,
aims at fundamentally non-material
(1)
goals (
Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: